This paper was converted on www.awesomepapers.org from LaTeX by an anonymous user.
Want to know more? Visit the Converter page.

A Stochastic Control Approach to Public Debt Management

Brachetta M.
matteo.brachetta@polimi.it
Department of Mathematics, Politecnico of Milan, Piazza Leonardo da Vinci, 32 - 20133 Milan. Corresponding author. ORCID: 0000-0001-6940-4749.
   Ceci, C.11footnotemark: 1
c.ceci@unich.it
Department of Economics, University of Chieti-Pescara, Viale Pindaro, 42 - 65127 Pescara, Italy. ORCID: 0000-0003-2796-6588.
Abstract

We discuss a class of debt management problems in a stochastic environment model. We propose a model for the debt-to-GDP (Gross Domestic Product) ratio where the government interventions via fiscal policies affect the public debt and the GDP growth rate at the same time. We allow for stochastic interest rate and possible correlation with the GDP growth rate through the dependence of both the processes (interest rate and GDP growth rate) on a stochastic factor which may represent any relevant macroeconomic variable, such as the state of economy. We tackle the problem of a government whose goal is to determine the fiscal policy in order to minimize a general functional cost. We prove that the value function is a viscosity solution to the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation and provide a Verification Theorem based on classical solutions. We investigate the form of the candidate optimal fiscal policy in many cases of interest, providing interesting policy insights. Finally, we discuss two applications to the debt reduction problem and debt smoothing, providing explicit expressions of the value function and the optimal policy in some special cases.

Keywords: Optimal stochastic control; government debt management; optimal fiscal policy; Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation.
JEL Classification codes: C02, C61, H63, E62.

1.   Introduction

Public debt management is a wide and complex topic in Economics. On the one hand, it is recognized the important role played by public debt in welfare improving, for example as a tax smoothing tool (starting from the seminal paper [2]) or as savings absorber (see [9] and [14] among others). On the other hand, the current high levels of debt in some developed countries has drawn the attention of many economists, especially because of possible effects on future taxation levels (see the quoted papers [9] and [14]).

The question of debt management, in broad sense, is up for discussion essentially because “we simply do not have a theory of the optimum debt level” (see [17]). However, in the very recent years some authors gave a rigorous mathematical formulation of a debt management problem, namely the optimal debt ceiling (that is the debt-to-GDP (Gross Domestic Product) ratio level at which the government should intervene in order to reduce it), see [4, 5, 11, 12, 6].

These works focus especially on the debt reduction problem of developed countries, where the government aims at reducing the debt-to-GDP ratio through the minimization of two costs: the cost of holding debt and the intervention cost (reducing public spending or increasing taxes). This study is motivated by the fact that concurrently with the financial crisis started in 2007, the debt-to-GDP ratios exploded.

In [4, 5, 11, 6] the possibility for the government to increase the level of debt ratio is precluded (fiscal deficit is not allowed) and any possible benefit resulting from holding debt is neglected. In practice, sometimes debt reduction policies might not be appropriate, since public investments in infrastructure, healthcare, education and research induce social and financial benefits (see [15]). In [12] policies of debt reduction and debt expansion are accounted by modeling controls of bounded variation and introducing, in addition to the cost of reduction policies, a benefit associated to expansionary policies.

Moreover, it is a well known evidence that policies of debt expansion (deficit) induce also an increase of the GDP growth rate of the country (which in turn could imply a reduction of the debt ratio) and this phenomenon is not exploited in the existing mathematical literature on the topic. This paper wishes to be a first effort to fill this lack.

We provide a rigorous mathematical formulation for a class of debt management problems, which are modeled as stochastic control problems. In particular, we tackle the problem of a government whose goal is to determine the fiscal policy in order to minimize a general functional cost, which depends on the debt-to-GDP ratio, an external driver (e.g. the state of economy) and the fiscal policy itself.

The main improvement of our debt-to-GDP model is that the GDP growth rate depends on the fiscal policy. In classical models, the GDP growth rate is assumed to be constant, see for instance [4, 5] and references therein. In [11, 12, 6] it is allowed to be a stochastic process, which may be modulated by an unobservable continuous time Markov chain as in [6]. However, in all these models the government’s interventions via fiscal measures do not affect the GDP growth rate, any policy of surplus decreases the debt ratio (see [4, 5, 11, 6]), whereas any deficit policy increases it (as in [12]). In the reality, the effects of the fiscal policy on the debt-to-GDP ratio is more complex.

For example, we might assume that the GDP growth rate decreases when the government increases its surplus (which is mostly the case in normal conditions). In this scenario, the gross debt will decrease as well, but the final effect on debt-to-GDP ratio is not unidirectional, contrary to classical models and the above quoted papers, where any surplus translates into debt ratio reduction. Indeed, the economics literature recognizes the possibility of achieving debt reduction via deficit policies, see for instance [9, 8, 10].

Moreover, we assume that both the interest rate on debt and the GDP growth rate are affected by a stochastic factor ZZ, which may represent the state of economy, the economic outlook, or any other macroeconomic variable. The presence of this external driver ZZ induces a correlation between the GDP growth rate and the interest rate, which is a well known phenomenon. Furthermore, we assume that ZZ and the GDP are driven by two correlated Brownian motion, so that we introduce an additional type of dependence. In practice, the macroeconomic conditions described by ZZ and the GDP have a common source of uncertainty.

In this framework we solve the problem of minimizing the expected total cost over an infinite time horizon. As mentioned above, the functional cost depends on the dynamics of the debt-to-GDP ratio, the exogenous factor ZZ and the fiscal policy. This is a very flexible and general problem formulation, which includes many debt management problems as special cases. For instance, we explore the applications to debt reduction and debt smoothing, which is the minimization of the distance between the current debt and a given threshold.

The mathematical contributions of the paper are the following. We rigorously derive the debt ratio dynamics, which is controlled by the government’s interventions (which include surplus and deficit strategies) and formulate the arising stochastic control problem. Under general assumptions on the functional cost, we prove that the value function is a continuous viscosity solution to the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) equation and provide a Verification Theorem which applies whenever the HJB equation has a classical solution. Next, we investigate the structure of the candidate optimal fiscal policy, discussing some cases of interest. In particular, when the functional cost is increasing on the debt ratio and does not explicitly depend by the control, we find that the optimal strategy depends only on the effect of the fiscal policy on the GDP growth rate, not by the current level of debt-to-GDP. A similar result was obtained in a different context by [1]. Thus it becomes crucial understanding how the government’s interventions via fiscal policies can influence the GDP growth rate of the country. To find more explicit solutions, we consider the example of a linear impact. Finally, we discuss two applications, namely debt reduction and debt smoothing and provide a numerical simulation for the second one.

The paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we propose and motivate our model formulation. In Section 3 we illustrate the optimization problem. In Section 4 we provide some properties of the value function. In Section 5 we prove that the value function is a solution in the viscosity sense to the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation and we provide a Verification Theorem based on classical solution. In Section 6 we discuss the minimization problem involved in the HJB equation. Finally, some special cases of interest are discussed in Section 7.

2.   Model formulation

We propose a stochastic model for the gross public debt and the gross domestic product (GDP) in presence of correlation between the interest rate on debt and the economic growth. Moreover, the government interventions through fiscal policies affect the GDP growth rate and the public debt at the same time.

Consider a complete probability space (Ω,,,𝔽)(\Omega,\mathcal{F},\mathbb{Q},\mathbb{F}) endowed with a complete and right continuous filtration 𝔽:={t}t0\mathbb{F}:=\{\mathcal{F}_{t}\}_{t\geq 0}. Let D={Dt}t0D=\{D_{t}\}_{t\geq 0} denote the gross public debt process and Y={Yt}t0Y=\{Y_{t}\}_{t\geq 0} the gross domestic product process of a country. According to classical models in economics literature (see [3] among others), the sovereign debt stock evolves as:

dDt=rDtdtdξt,D0>0,dD_{t}=rD_{t}\,dt-d\xi_{t}\;,\quad D_{0}>0\;,

where r>0r>0 denotes the real interest rate on debt and ξ\xi is the fiscal policy, with the convention that positive values correspond to primary surplus, while negative values represent deficit. We extend the model by introducing a stochastic interest rate of the form rt=r(Zt)r_{t}=r(Z_{t}), with rr a positive measurable function and Z={Zt}t>0Z=\{Z_{t}\}_{t>0} a stochastic factor described by the following stochastic differential equation (SDE):

dZt=bZ(Zt)dt+σZ(Zt)dWtZ,Z0=z,dZ_{t}=b_{Z}(Z_{t})\,dt+\sigma_{Z}(Z_{t})\,dW^{Z}_{t}\;,\qquad Z_{0}=z\in\mathbb{R}\;, (2.1)

where WZ={WtZ}t0W^{Z}=\{W^{Z}_{t}\}_{t\geq 0} is a standard Brownian motion. We assume existence and strong uniqueness of the solution to the SDE (2.1). The process ZZ describes any stochastic factor, such as underlying macroeconomic conditions, which affects the interest rate on debt of the country.

Let u={ut}t0u=\{u_{t}\}_{t\geq 0} be the rate of the primary balance expressed in terms of the debt, that is dξt=utDtdtd\xi_{t}=u_{t}D_{t}dt. We assume that the real GDP growth rate at time tt is of the form g(Zt,ut)g(Z_{t},u_{t}), with g(z,u)g(z,u) being a measurable function of its arguments. Precisely, the pair (D,Y)(D,Y) follows

{dDt=Dt(r(Zt)ut)dt,D0>0,dYt=Yt(g(Zt,ut)dt+σdW~t),Y0>0,\begin{cases}dD_{t}=D_{t}(r(Z_{t})-u_{t})\,dt\;,\quad D_{0}>0\;,\\ dY_{t}=Y_{t}(g(Z_{t},u_{t})\,dt+\sigma\,d\widetilde{W}_{t})\;,\quad Y_{0}>0\;,\end{cases} (2.2)

where W~={W~t}t>0\widetilde{W}=\{\widetilde{W}_{t}\}_{t>0} a standard Brownian motion correlated with WZW^{Z} and σ>0\sigma>0 is the GDP volatility.

The debt-to-GDP ratio X={Xt=DtYt}t0X=\{X_{t}=\frac{D_{t}}{Y_{t}}\}_{t\geq 0} dynamics can be derived by Itô’s formula:

dXt=1Yt(r(Zt)ut)DtdtDtYt2Yt(g(Zt,ut)dt+σdW~t)+DtYt3σ2Yt2dt=Xt(r(Zt)g(Zt,ut)ut)dt+Xtσ(σdtdW~t),X0=D0Y0.\begin{split}dX_{t}&=\frac{1}{Y_{t}}\big{(}r(Z_{t})-u_{t}\big{)}D_{t}dt-\frac{D_{t}}{Y_{t}^{2}}Y_{t}(g(Z_{t},u_{t})\,dt+\sigma\,d\widetilde{W}_{t})+\frac{D_{t}}{Y_{t}^{3}}\sigma^{2}Y_{t}^{2}\,dt\\ &=X_{t}\big{(}r(Z_{t})-g(Z_{t},u_{t})-u_{t}\big{)}\,dt+X_{t}\sigma(\sigma\,dt-d\widetilde{W}_{t})\;,\qquad X_{0}=\frac{D_{0}}{Y_{0}}\;.\end{split}

Now we can introduce a new measure \mathbb{P}, equivalent to \mathbb{Q}, such that W={Wt}t0={σtW~t}t0W=\{W_{t}\}_{t\geq 0}=\{\sigma t-\widetilde{W}_{t}\}_{t\geq 0} is a \mathbb{P}-Brownian motion and WZW^{Z} remains a \mathbb{P}-Brownian motion.

Hence, under \mathbb{P}, the debt ratio Xu,x={Xtu,x}t0X^{u,x}=\{X^{u,x}_{t}\}_{t\geq 0} is a controlled process which solves the following SDE:

dXtu,x=Xtu,x[(r(Zt)g(Zt,ut)ut)dt+σdWt],X0u,x=x,dX^{u,x}_{t}=X^{u,x}_{t}[(r(Z_{t})-g(Z_{t},u_{t})-u_{t})\,dt+\sigma\,dW_{t}]\;,\qquad X^{u,x}_{0}=x\;, (2.3)

where x>0x>0 is the initial debt-to-GDP ratio and the control u={ut}t0u=\{u_{t}\}_{t\geq 0} denotes the fiscal policy (i.e. the ratio of primary surplus to gross debt).

Let us remark some aspects of our model, which is different from those usually introduced in the existing literature:

  1. 1.

    This model extends the one considered in [4] and [5] where rr and gg are constant. Our main improvement is that the GDP growth rate is now affected by the fiscal policy. For instance, if we take a function gg decreasing in uu, we capture a well known effect: when the government generates surplus, the debt stock is reduced and, at the same time, the GDP is so. Hence the final effect on the debt-to-GDP ratio is not unidirectional as in the models proposed in [4, 5, 11] and [6], where any surplus translates to debt-to-GDP reduction.

  2. 2.

    Another property of our model is that the interest rate and the GDP growth rate have a common source of uncertainty, which is modeled through the external driver ZZ. In many applications ZZ could represent the economic environment, the state of the economy, the economic outlook. The pathwise measurement of covariance between the interest rate and the GDP growth rate is given by the covariation between the two processes. When the functions rr and gg are sufficiently regular w.r.t. zz\in\mathbb{R}, from Itô’s formula it can be computed for any fixed uu:

    <r(Zt),g(Zt,u)>=0tgz(Zs,u)r(Zs)σZ2(Zs)𝑑s.<r(Z_{t}),g(Z_{t},u)>=\int_{0}^{t}\frac{\partial{g}}{\partial{z}}(Z_{s},u)r^{\prime}(Z_{s})\sigma^{2}_{Z}(Z_{s})ds\;.

    In particular, this implies that

    𝔼[r(Zt)g(Zt,u)]=𝔼[0tgz(Zs,u)r(Zs)σZ2(Zs)𝑑s].\mathbb{E}[r(Z_{t})g(Z_{t},u)]=\mathbb{E}[\int_{0}^{t}\frac{\partial{g}}{\partial{z}}(Z_{s},u)r^{\prime}(Z_{s})\sigma^{2}_{Z}(Z_{s})ds]\;.
  3. 3.

    Moreover, our model takes into account possible correlation between the Brownian motions WZW^{Z} and WW driving the dynamics of the environmental stochastic factor process ZZ and the debt-to-GDP process XX, respectively. For instance, there could be a common source of uncertainty between debt-to-GDP and macroeconomics conditions.

In the sequel we assume the following hypotheses.

Assumption 2.1.

The following assumptions are required in the sequel:

  • r:(0,+)r\colon\mathbb{R}\to(0,+\infty), i.e. the interest rate on debt, is such that r(z)Rr(z)\leq R z\forall z\in\mathbb{R} for a given constant R>0R>0;

  • utu_{t}, i.e. the surplus (or deficit)-to-debt ratio at time t>0t>0, takes values in a compact set [U1,U2][-U_{1},U_{2}], where U1>0U_{1}>0 denotes the maximum allowed deficit-to-debt ratio and U2>0U_{2}>0 is the maximum surplus-to-debt;

  • g:×[U1,U2]g\colon\mathbb{R}\times[-U_{1},U_{2}]\to\mathbb{R}, which represents the GDP growth rate, is bounded by

    g¯1g(z,u)g¯2(z,u)×[U1,U2],\bar{g}_{1}\leq g(z,u)\leq\bar{g}_{2}\qquad\forall(z,u)\in\mathbb{R}\times[-U_{1},U_{2}]\;, (2.4)

    for some suitable constants g¯1<0<g¯2\bar{g}_{1}<0<\bar{g}_{2}.

Example 2.1.

We consider the case where the fiscal policy has a linear impact on the GDP growth rate, precisely

g(z,u)=g0(z)α(z)u,g(z,u)=g_{0}(z)-\alpha(z)u\;, (2.5)

with g0:g_{0}\colon\mathbb{R}\to\mathbb{R}, α:(0,+)\alpha\colon\mathbb{R}\to(0,+\infty) measurable and bounded functions. The process {g0(Zt)}t0\{g_{0}(Z_{t})\}_{t\geq 0} is the GDP growth rate when no intervention is considered and depends on the environment stochastic factor ZZ. Any positive intervention ut>0u_{t}>0 leads to a reduction of the GDP growth rate g(Zt,ut)g(Z_{t},u_{t}). Conversely, any negative intervention ut<0u_{t}<0 leads to an increase of the GDP growth rate g(Zt,ut)g(Z_{t},u_{t}). Both the effects are modulated by the environment stochastic factor ZZ via the coefficient α(Zt)\alpha(Z_{t}). A simplified model can be obtained with α(z)=α1\alpha(z)=\alpha\neq 1 z\forall z\in\mathbb{R}, that is

g(z,u)=g0(z)αu.g(z,u)=g_{0}(z)-\alpha u\;. (2.6)

In this special case, equation (2.3) reduces to

dXtu,x=Xtu,x[(r(Zt)g0(Zt)(1α)ut)dt+σdWt],X0u,x=x.dX^{u,x}_{t}=X^{u,x}_{t}[(r(Z_{t})-g_{0}(Z_{t})-(1-\alpha)u_{t})\,dt+\sigma\,dW_{t}]\;,\qquad X^{u,x}_{0}=x\;. (2.7)

Clearly, 0<α<10<\alpha<1 means that the effect of the government fiscal policy with ut>0u_{t}>0 (surplus) leads to a reduction of the instantaneous debt-to-GDP growth rate, while α>1\alpha>1 leads to a reduction of the instantaneous debt-to-GDP growth rate when ut<0u_{t}<0 (deficit). This occurs because, for 0<α<10<\alpha<1, the government fiscal policy has a smaller effect on the GDP growth rate w.r.t. the debt growth rate (see the first equation in (2.2)), while for α>1\alpha>1 the fiscal policy has a larger effect on the GDP growth rate thank on debt growth rate.

For the sake of notation simplicity we make use of the following convention.

Notation 2.1.

The dynamics of Xu,xX^{u,x}, see equation (2.3), must be assigned together with equation (2.1). However, when the expectations are considered we will neglect the conditioning to Z0=zZ_{0}=z, so that the two notations below are equivalent for us:

𝔼[Xtu,xZ0=z]=𝔼[Xtu,x].\mathbb{E}[X^{u,x}_{t}\mid Z_{0}=z]=\mathbb{E}[X^{u,x}_{t}]\;.

We will use the left hand notation either to specify a different initial value of ZZ or to emphasize the dependence of ZZ.

Remark 2.1.

Let us observe that the SDE (2.3) admits an explicit solution:

Xtu,x=xe0t(r(Zs)g(Zs,us)us)𝑑s12σ2teσWtt0,a.s..X^{u,x}_{t}=xe^{\int_{0}^{t}(r(Z_{s})-g(Z_{s},u_{s})-u_{s})\,ds-\frac{1}{2}\sigma^{2}t}e^{\sigma W_{t}}\quad\forall t\geq 0,\;\mathbb{P}-a.s.\;. (2.8)

Thus by Assumption 2.1, for any m>0m>0 we have that

xmem(g¯2+U2)tem2σ2t+mσWt(Xtu,x)mxmem(Rg¯1+U1)tem2σ2t+mσWtt0,a.s.x^{m}e^{-m(\bar{g}_{2}+U_{2})t}e^{-\frac{m}{2}\sigma^{2}t+m\sigma W_{t}}\leq(X^{u,x}_{t})^{m}\leq x^{m}e^{m(R-\bar{g}_{1}+U_{1})t}e^{-\frac{m}{2}\sigma^{2}t+m\sigma W_{t}}\quad\forall t\geq 0,\;\mathbb{P}-a.s.

from which we get this estimation:

𝔼[(Xtu,x)m]xmeλmtt0,\mathbb{E}[(X^{u,x}_{t})^{m}]\leq x^{m}e^{\lambda_{m}t}\quad\forall t\geq 0\;, (2.9)

where

λmm(Rg¯1+U1)+m(m1)σ22,\lambda_{m}\doteq m(R-\bar{g}_{1}+U_{1})+m(m-1)\frac{\sigma^{2}}{2}\;, (2.10)
Remark 2.2.

We can show that the condition r(z)g(z,0)Gr(z)-g(z,0)\geq G z\forall z\in\mathbb{R}, for some constant G>0G>0, implies an explosive debt-to-GDP ratio when no intervention is considered. Indeed, by equation (2.8) we have that

Xt0,x=xe0t(r(Zs)g(Zs,0))𝑑se12σ2t+σWtxeGtMtX^{0,x}_{t}=xe^{\int_{0}^{t}(r(Z_{s})-g(Z_{s},0))\,ds}e^{-\frac{1}{2}\sigma^{2}t+\sigma W_{t}}\geq xe^{Gt}M_{t} (2.11)

where Mt=e12σ2t+σWtM_{t}=e^{-\frac{1}{2}\sigma^{2}t+\sigma W_{t}} denotes the well known exponential martingale with 𝔼[Mt]=1\mathbb{E}[M_{t}]=1 t0\forall t\geq 0. Hence

limt+𝔼[Xt0,x]limt+xeGt=+,\lim_{t\to+\infty}\mathbb{E}[X^{0,x}_{t}]\geq\lim_{t\to+\infty}xe^{Gt}=+\infty\;,

which implies limt+Xt0,x=+\lim_{t\to+\infty}X^{0,x}_{t}=+\infty a.s.\mathbb{P}-a.s.. However, when rr and gg are constant functions, the debt explodes if rg>0r-g>0, which is a popular result in economics literature.

An important feature for a country is to apply fiscal policies which are sustainable. An explosive debt-to-GDP ratio is not a problem for a country if the discounted debt-to-GDP ratio w.r.t. the interest rate on debt converges to 0. The following definition is standard in Economics (see e.g. [13]).

Definition 2.1.

A fiscal policy uu is called sustainable if it realizes

limt+e0tr(Zs)𝑑sXtu,x=0a.s.,\lim_{t\to+\infty}e^{-\int_{0}^{t}r(Z_{s})\,ds}X^{u,x}_{t}=0\qquad\mathbb{P}-a.s.\;, (2.12)

see e.g. [3].

Remark 2.3.

The bounds UiU_{i}, i=1,2i=1,2, depend by structural economic and political characteristics of the country, in general. It seems reasonable to choose the maximum level of deficit and surplus, UiU_{i}, i=1,2i=1,2, respectively, by imposing that the fiscal policies identically equal to these maximum levels (i.e. ut1=U1u^{1}_{t}=-U_{1} and ut2=U2u^{2}_{t}=U_{2} t0\forall t\geq 0) turn out to be sustainable for the country, i.e.

limt+e0tr(Zs)𝑑sXtU1,x=0,limt+e0tr(Zs)𝑑sXtU2,x=0a.s..\lim_{t\to+\infty}e^{-\int_{0}^{t}r(Z_{s})\,ds}X^{-U_{1},x}_{t}=0\;,\quad\lim_{t\to+\infty}e^{-\int_{0}^{t}r(Z_{s})\,ds}X^{U_{2},x}_{t}=0\quad\mathbb{P}-a.s.\;. (2.13)

For instance, in case of linear GDP growth rate as in (2.5), we get that

𝔼[e0tr(Zs)𝑑sXtU1,x]=x𝔼[e0t(g0(Zs)U1(1α))𝑑sMt]\mathbb{E}[e^{-\int_{0}^{t}r(Z_{s})\,ds}X^{-U_{1},x}_{t}]=x\mathbb{E}[e^{-\int_{0}^{t}(g_{0}(Z_{s})-U_{1}(1-\alpha))\,ds}M_{t}]

and

𝔼[e0tr(Zs)𝑑sXtU2,x]=x𝔼[e0t(g0(Zs)+U2(1α))𝑑sMt]\mathbb{E}[e^{-\int_{0}^{t}r(Z_{s})\,ds}X^{U_{2},x}_{t}]=x\mathbb{E}[e^{-\int_{0}^{t}(g_{0}(Z_{s})+U_{2}(1-\alpha))\,ds}M_{t}]

(here we recall that Mt=e12σ2t+σWtM_{t}=e^{-\frac{1}{2}\sigma^{2}t+\sigma W_{t}}). Let g¯0=minzg0(z)\underline{g}_{0}=\min_{z\in\mathbb{R}}g_{0}(z) we get

𝔼[e0tr(Zs)𝑑sXtU1,x]xe(g¯0U1(1α))t,\mathbb{E}[e^{-\int_{0}^{t}r(Z_{s})\,ds}X^{-U_{1},x}_{t}]\leq xe^{-(\underline{g}_{0}-U_{1}(1-\alpha))t}\;,
𝔼[e0tr(Zs)𝑑sXtU2,x]xe(g¯0+U2(1α))t,\mathbb{E}[e^{-\int_{0}^{t}r(Z_{s})\,ds}X^{U_{2},x}_{t}]\leq xe^{-(\underline{g}_{0}+U_{2}(1-\alpha))t}\;,

which imply that if U1U_{1} and U2U_{2} satisfy

U1(1α)<g¯0,U2(α1)<g¯0,U_{1}(1-\alpha)<\underline{g}_{0},\quad U_{2}(\alpha-1)<\underline{g}_{0}\;,

both the fiscal policies ut1=U1u^{1}_{t}=-U_{1} t0\forall t\geq 0 and ut2=U2u^{2}_{t}=U_{2} t0\forall t\geq 0 are sustainable. The economic interpretation is clear: when the maximum deficit positive impact on GDP growth is greater than the effect on debt, then U1-U_{1} is sustainable. Similarly, when the negative effect of the maximum surplus on GDP is surpassed by the positive effect on debt reduction, then U2U_{2} becomes sustainable.

3.   Problem formulation

Let us recall the dynamics of debt-to-GDP ratio:

{dXtu,x=Xtu,x[(r(Zt)g(Zt,ut)ut)dt+σdWt],X0u,x=x,dZt=bZ(Zt)dt+σZ(Zt)dWtZ,Z0=z.\begin{cases}dX^{u,x}_{t}=X^{u,x}_{t}[(r(Z_{t})-g(Z_{t},u_{t})-u_{t})\,dt+\sigma\,dW_{t}]\;,&X^{u,x}_{0}=x\;,\\ dZ_{t}=b_{Z}(Z_{t})\,dt+\sigma_{Z}(Z_{t})\,dW^{Z}_{t}\;,&Z_{0}=z\in\mathbb{R}\;.\end{cases}

We denote by ρ[1,1]\rho\in[-1,1] the correlation coefficient between WW and WZW^{Z}.

We consider the problem of a government which wants to choose the fiscal policy in order to optimally manage the sovereign debt. For this purpose we introduce the class of admissible fiscal strategies.

Definition 3.1 (Admissible fiscal policies).

We denote by 𝒰\mathcal{U} the family of all the 𝔽\mathbb{F}-predictable and [U1,U2][-U_{1},U_{2}]-valued processes u={ut}t0u=\{u_{t}\}_{t\geq 0}.

The main goal will be to minimize the following objective function:

J(x,z,u)=𝔼[0+eλtf(Xtu,x,Zt,ut)𝑑tZ0=z],(x,z)(0,+)×,u𝒰,J(x,z,u)=\mathbb{E}\biggl{[}\int_{0}^{+\infty}e^{-\lambda t}f(X^{u,x}_{t},Z_{t},u_{t})\,dt\mid Z_{0}=z\biggr{]},\qquad(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R},u\in\mathcal{U}\;, (3.1)

where λ>0\lambda>0 is the government discounting factor and f:(0,+)××[U1,U2][0,+)f\colon(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}\times[-U_{1},U_{2}]\to[0,+\infty) is a cost function satisfying the following hypotheses.

Assumption 3.1.

We assume that

  • ff is nonnegative;

  • C>0\exists C>0 and m>0m>0 such that

    f(x,z,u)C(1+xm)(x,z,u)(0,+)××[U1,U2],f(x,z,u)\leq C(1+x^{m})\qquad\forall(x,z,u)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}\times[-U_{1},U_{2}]\;,
  • λ>λm\lambda>\lambda_{m} (see equation (2.10)).

We observe that our problem formulation is very general and flexible. The cost function depends on the debt-to-GDP ratio, which has to be controlled, and the government can take into account fluctuations of the stochastic factor ZZ. For instance, when ZZ represents the state of economy, countercyclical policies are allowed. In addition to this, the fiscal policy level can be explicitly controlled as well. Clearly, many operational problems can be addressed in this framework, depending on the configuration that the government assigns to the function ff. We will investigate some applications in Section 7.

As announced, the government problem can be formalized in this way:

v(x,z)=infu𝒰J(x,z,u),(x,z)(0,+)×.v(x,z)=\inf_{u\in\mathcal{U}}J(x,z,u)\;,\qquad(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}\;. (3.2)
Proposition 3.1.

Every admissible strategy u𝒰u\in\mathcal{U} is such that J(x,z,u)<+J(x,z,u)<+\infty, (x,z)(0,+)×\forall(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}.

Proof.

Under Assumptions 2.1 and 3.1 and recalling (2.9), we get that u𝒰\forall u\in\mathcal{U}, and (x,z)(0,+)×(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}

J(x,z,u)\displaystyle J(x,z,u) =𝔼[0+eλtf(Xtu,x,Zt,ut)𝑑t]\displaystyle=\mathbb{E}\biggl{[}\int_{0}^{+\infty}e^{-\lambda t}f(X^{u,x}_{t},Z_{t},u_{t})\,dt\biggr{]}
C𝔼[0+eλt(Xtu,x)m𝑑t+0+eλt𝑑t]\displaystyle\leq C\mathbb{E}\biggl{[}\int_{0}^{+\infty}e^{-\lambda t}(X^{u,x}_{t})^{m}\,dt+\int_{0}^{+\infty}e^{-\lambda t}\,dt\biggr{]}
Cxm0+e(λmλ)t𝑑t+Cλ\displaystyle\leq Cx^{m}\int_{0}^{+\infty}e^{(\lambda_{m}-\lambda)t}\,dt+\frac{C}{\lambda}
=Cxmλλm+Cλ<+.\displaystyle=\frac{Cx^{m}}{\lambda-\lambda_{m}}+\frac{C}{\lambda}<+\infty\;. (3.3)

4.   Properties of the value function

In this section we explore some properties of the value function.

Proposition 4.1.

The value function given in (3.2) satisfies the following properties:

  • v(x,z)0v(x,z)\geq 0 (x,z)(0,+)×\forall(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R};

  • M>0\exists M>0 such that v(x,z)M(1+xm)v(x,z)\leq M(1+x^{m}) (x,z)(0,+)×\forall(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}.

If in addition C~>0\exists\tilde{C}>0 such that f(x,z,0)C~xmf(x,z,0)\leq\tilde{C}x^{m} (x,z)(0,+)×\forall(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R} for some m>0m>0, then

  • M~>0\exists\tilde{M}>0 such that v(x,z)M~xmv(x,z)\leq\tilde{M}x^{m} (x,z)(0,+)×\forall(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R};

  • v(0+,z)=0v(0^{+},z)=0 z\forall z\in\mathbb{R}.

Proof.

Using Assumption 3.1, we easily obtain that vv is nonnegative. Now manipulating equation (3.3) we obtain that u𝒰\forall u\in\mathcal{U}, and (x,z)(0,+)×(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}

J(x,z,u)Cλλm(xm+λλmλ)Cλλm(1+xm),\begin{split}J(x,z,u)&\leq\frac{C}{\lambda-\lambda_{m}}\biggl{(}x^{m}+\frac{\lambda-\lambda_{m}}{\lambda}\biggr{)}\\ &\leq\frac{C}{\lambda-\lambda_{m}}(1+x^{m})\;,\end{split}

hence v(x,z)M(1+xm)v(x,z)\leq M(1+x^{m}) (x,z)(0,+)×\forall(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R} with M=CλλmM=\frac{C}{\lambda-\lambda_{m}}. Now we assume that f(x,z,0)C~xmf(x,z,0)\leq\tilde{C}x^{m} (x,z)(0,+)×\forall(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}. Then

v(x,z)J(x,z,0)M~xm,v(x,z)\leq J(x,z,0)\leq\tilde{M}x^{m}\;,

choosing M~=C~λλm\tilde{M}=\frac{\tilde{C}}{\lambda-\lambda_{m}} (by imitation of the proof of Proposition 3.1). This in turn implies that

0v(x,z)M~xm(x,z)(0,+)×v(0+,z)=0z.0\leq v(x,z)\leq\tilde{M}x^{m}\quad\forall(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}\quad\Rightarrow\quad v(0^{+},z)=0\quad\forall z\in\mathbb{R}\;.

Proposition 4.2.

Suppose that ff is increasing in x(0,+)x\in(0,+\infty). Then vv is increasing in x>0x>0, i.e. 0<xxv(x,z)v(x,z)0<x\leq x^{\prime}\Rightarrow v(x,z)\leq v(x^{\prime},z) z\forall z\in\mathbb{R}.

Proof.

Let us take 0<xx0<x\leq x^{\prime}. By equation (2.8) we see that u𝒰\forall u\in\mathcal{U}, Xtu,xXtu,xX^{u,x}_{t}\leq X^{u,x^{\prime}}_{t} t0\forall t\geq 0 a.s.\mathbb{P}-a.s.. Using the monotonicity of ff we get that

𝔼[0+eλtf(Xtu,x,Zt,ut)𝑑t]𝔼[0+eλtf(Xtu,x,Zt,ut)𝑑t]u𝒰.\mathbb{E}\biggl{[}\int_{0}^{+\infty}e^{-\lambda t}f(X^{u,x}_{t},Z_{t},u_{t})\,dt\biggr{]}\leq\mathbb{E}\biggl{[}\int_{0}^{+\infty}e^{-\lambda t}f(X^{u,x^{\prime}}_{t},Z_{t},u_{t})\,dt\biggr{]}\qquad\forall u\in\mathcal{U}\;.

Taking the infimum over 𝒰\mathcal{U} of both sides, we obtain our statement. ∎

The following proposition is also useful when infinite horizon problems are studied.

Proposition 4.3.

This result hold true, u𝒰\forall u\in\mathcal{U}, and (x,z)(0,+)×(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}

limT+eλT𝔼[v(XTu,x,z)]=0.\lim_{T\to+\infty}e^{-\lambda T}\mathbb{E}[v(X^{u,x}_{T},z)]=0\;.
Proof.

Using Proposition 4.1 and equation (2.9) we find that

eλT𝔼[v(XTu,x,z)]eλTM(1+𝔼[(XTu,x)m])eλTM(1+xmeλmT).\begin{split}e^{-\lambda T}\mathbb{E}[v(X^{u,x}_{T},z)]&\leq e^{-\lambda T}M(1+\mathbb{E}[(X^{u,x}_{T})^{m}])\\ &\leq e^{-\lambda T}M(1+x^{m}e^{\lambda_{m}T})\;.\end{split}

Taking T+T\to+\infty, this quantity converges to 0 since λ>λm\lambda>\lambda_{m}. ∎

Proposition 4.4.

Suppose that ff is convex in x>0x>0. Moreover, assume that an optimal control u𝒰u^{*}\in\mathcal{U} exists for the problem (3.2) for any (x,z)(0,+)×(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}. Then the value function in (3.2) is convex in x(0,+)x\in(0,+\infty).

Proof.

Let us take zz\in\mathbb{R}, x,x>0x,x^{\prime}>0 and k[0,1]k\in[0,1]. Defining xk=kx+(1k)xx_{k}=kx+(1-k)x^{\prime}, by equation (2.8) we easily get that, u𝒰\forall u\in\mathcal{U}

Xtu,xk=(kx+(1k)x)e0t(r(Zs)g(Zs,us)us)𝑑s12σ2teσWt=kXtu,x+(1k)Xtu,xt0,a.s..\begin{split}X^{u,x_{k}}_{t}&=(kx+(1-k)x^{\prime})\,e^{\int_{0}^{t}(r(Z_{s})-g(Z_{s},u_{s})-u_{s})\,ds-\frac{1}{2}\sigma^{2}t}e^{\sigma W_{t}}\\ &=kX^{u,x}_{t}+(1-k)X^{u,x^{\prime}}_{t}\qquad\forall t\geq 0,\mathbb{P}-a.s.\;.\end{split}

Now the convexity of ff w.r.t. the first variable xx\in\mathbb{R}, implies that, u𝒰\forall u\in\mathcal{U}

f(Xtu,xk,Zt,ut)=f(kXtu,x+(1k)Xtu,x,Zt,ut)kf(Xtu,x,Zt,ut)+(1k)f(Xtu,x,Zt,ut)t0,a.s..\begin{split}f(X^{u,x_{k}}_{t},Z_{t},u_{t})&=f(kX^{u,x}_{t}+(1-k)X^{u,x^{\prime}}_{t},Z_{t},u_{t})\\ &\leq kf(X^{u,x}_{t},Z_{t},u_{t})+(1-k)f(X^{u,x^{\prime}}_{t},Z_{t},u_{t})\qquad\forall t\geq 0,\mathbb{P}-a.s.\;.\end{split}

Hence

J(xk,z,u)=𝔼[0+eλtf(Xtu,xk,Zt,ut)𝑑t]kJ(x,z,u)+(1k)J(x,z,u)u𝒰.\begin{split}J(x_{k},z,u)&=\mathbb{E}\biggl{[}\int_{0}^{+\infty}e^{-\lambda t}f(X^{u,x_{k}}_{t},Z_{t},u_{t})\,dt\biggr{]}\\ &\leq kJ(x,z,u)+(1-k)J(x^{\prime},z,u)\qquad\forall u\in\mathcal{U}\;.\end{split}

Taking the infimum over u𝒰u\in\mathcal{U} in the left side yields

v(xk,z)kJ(x,z,u)+(1k)J(x,z,u)u𝒰.v(x_{k},z)\leq kJ(x,z,u)+(1-k)J(x^{\prime},z,u)\qquad\forall u\in\mathcal{U}\;.

Taking u=uu=u^{*} we finally get that

v(xk,z)kJ(x,z,u)+(1k)J(x,z,u)=kv(x,z)+(1k)v(x,z).v(x_{k},z)\leq kJ(x,z,u^{*})+(1-k)J(x^{\prime},z,u^{*})=kv(x,z)+(1-k)v(x^{\prime},z)\;.

Proposition 4.5.

Let us assume the following hypotheses:

  • bZb_{Z} and σZ\sigma_{Z} are Lipschitz continuous functions on zz\in\mathbb{R};

  • ff is continuous in (x,z)(0,+)×(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}, uniformly in u[U1,U2]u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}];

  • rr is continuous in zz\in\mathbb{R};

  • gg is continuous in zz\in\mathbb{R}, uniformly in u[U1,U2]u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}].

Then the value function is continuous in (x,z)(0,+)×(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}.

Proof.

Let us denote by (Xu,x,z,Zz)={(Xtu,x,z,Ztz)}t0(X^{u,x,z},Z^{z})=\{(X^{u,x,z}_{t},Z^{z}_{t})\}_{t\geq 0} the solution to the system of equations (2.1) and (2.3) with initial data (x,z)(0,+)×(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}. By classical results on SDE, the process ZzZ^{z} depends continuously on the initial data zz\in\mathbb{R}, moreover by (2.8) we have that for any u𝒰u\in\mathcal{U}

Xtu,x,z=xe0t(r(Zsz)g(Zsz,us)us)𝑑s12σ2teσWtt0,a.s..X^{u,x,z}_{t}=xe^{\int_{0}^{t}(r(Z^{z}_{s})-g(Z^{z}_{s},u_{s})-u_{s})\,ds-\frac{1}{2}\sigma^{2}t}e^{\sigma W_{t}}\qquad\forall t\geq 0,\mathbb{P}-a.s.\;.

Let {(xn,zn)}n0\{(x_{n},z_{n})\}_{n\geq 0} be any sequence in (0,+)×(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R} converging to (x,z)(0,+)×(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R} as n+n\to+\infty, then ZtznZtzZ^{z_{n}}_{t}\to Z^{z}_{t} t0\forall t\geq 0, as n+n\to+\infty and by the dominated convergence theorem we have that t0\forall t\geq 0

Xtu,xn,znXtu,x,zuniformly onu𝒰,asn+X^{u,x_{n},z_{n}}_{t}\to X^{u,x,z}_{t}\qquad\text{uniformly on}\;u\in\mathcal{U}\;,\text{as}\;n\to+\infty

and

J(xn,zn,u)J(x,z,u)uniformly onu𝒰,asn+,J(x_{n},z_{n},u)\to J(x,z,u)\qquad\text{uniformly on}\;u\in\mathcal{U}\;,\text{as}\;n\to+\infty\;,

which finally implies continuity of v(x,z)=infu𝒰J(x,z,u)v(x,z)=\inf_{u\in\mathcal{U}}J(x,z,u) in (x,z)(0,+)×(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}. ∎

5.   Characterization of the value function

In this section we aim to characterize the value function vv given in equation (3.2). Precisely, we prove that it is a viscosity solution of the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation associated to our problem (see equation (5.2) below). To obtain this result only the continuity of vv is required. If, in addition, the HJB equation admits a classical solution, then it turns out to be the value function. In this case vv will satisfy some additional regularity conditions.

We begin finding the HJB equation associated to our problem.

Remark 5.1.

For any (x,z)(0,+)×(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R} and any u[U1,U2]u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}] the Markov generator of (Xu,Z)(X^{u},Z) is given by the following differential operator111This is a simple application of Itô’s formula.:

uϕ(x,z)=x[r(z)g(z,u)u]ϕx(x,z)+12σ2x22ϕx2(x,z)+ρσxσZ(z)2ϕxz(x,z)+Zϕ(x,z),\mathcal{L}^{u}\phi(x,z)=x[r(z)-g(z,u)-u]\frac{\partial{\phi}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)+\frac{1}{2}\sigma^{2}x^{2}\frac{\partial^{2}{\phi}}{\partial{x^{2}}}(x,z)+\rho\sigma x\sigma_{Z}(z)\frac{\partial^{2}{\phi}}{\partial{x}\partial{z}}(x,z)+\mathcal{L}^{Z}\phi(x,z)\;, (5.1)

where ϕ:(0,+)×\phi\colon(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}\to\mathbb{R} is a function on 𝒞2,2((0,+)×)\mathcal{C}^{2,2}((0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}) and Z\mathcal{L}^{Z} denotes the operator

Zϕ(x,z)=bZ(z)ϕz(x,z)+12σZ(z)22ϕz2(x,z).\mathcal{L}^{Z}\phi(x,z)=b_{Z}(z)\frac{\partial{\phi}}{\partial{z}}(x,z)+\frac{1}{2}\sigma_{Z}(z)^{2}\frac{\partial^{2}{\phi}}{\partial{z^{2}}}(x,z)\;.

The value function in equation (3.2), if sufficiently regular, is expected to solve the HJB equation, which is given by

infu[U1,U2]{uv(x,z)+f(x,z,u)λv(x,z)}=0.\inf_{u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}]}\{\mathcal{L}^{u}v(x,z)+f(x,z,u)-\lambda v(x,z)\}=0\;. (5.2)

Before stating the main result, we briefly recall the definition of viscosity solution to equation (5.2). Let us notice that, in general, one would require that a function ww is locally bounded in order to be the solution of a PDE in viscosity sense (see for instance [16, Chapter 4]). However, we already know that vv given in equation (3.2) is continuous, hence we can directly refer to the special case of continuous functions.

Definition 5.1.

Let w:(0,+)×[0,+)w\colon(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}\to[0,+\infty) be continuous. We say that

  • ww is a viscosity subsolution of equation (5.2) if

    infu[U1,U2]{uφ(x¯,z¯)+f(x¯,z¯,u)λφ(x¯,z¯)}0,\inf_{u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}]}\{\mathcal{L}^{u}\varphi(\bar{x},\bar{z})+f(\bar{x},\bar{z},u)-\lambda\varphi(\bar{x},\bar{z})\}\geq 0\;, (5.3)

    for all (x¯,z¯)(0,+)×(\bar{x},\bar{z})\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R} and for all φ𝒞2,2((0,+)×)\varphi\in\mathcal{C}^{2,2}((0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}) such that (x¯,z¯)(\bar{x},\bar{z}) is a maximum point of wφw-\varphi;

  • ww is a viscosity supersolution of equation (5.2) if

    infu[U1,U2]{uφ(x¯,z¯)+f(x¯,z¯,u)λφ(x¯,z¯)}0,\inf_{u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}]}\{\mathcal{L}^{u}\varphi(\bar{x},\bar{z})+f(\bar{x},\bar{z},u)-\lambda\varphi(\bar{x},\bar{z})\}\leq 0\;, (5.4)

    for all (x¯,z¯)(0,+)×(\bar{x},\bar{z})\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R} and for all φ𝒞2,2((0,+)×)\varphi\in\mathcal{C}^{2,2}((0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}) such that (x¯,z¯)(\bar{x},\bar{z}) is a minimum point of wφw-\varphi;

  • ww is a viscosity solution of equation (5.2) if it is a viscosity subsolution and a supersolution.

Theorem 5.1.

Under the hypotheses of Proposition 4.5, the value function vv given in equation (3.2) is a viscosity solution of the HJB equation (5.2).

Proof.

We adapt the proof of [16, Chapter 4.3] to our framework. Proposition 4.5 ensures the continuity of vv. Let (x¯,z¯)(0,+)×(\bar{x},\bar{z})\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R} and take a test function φ𝒞2,2((0,+)×)\varphi\in\mathcal{C}^{2,2}((0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}) such that

0=(vφ)(x¯,z¯)=max(x,z)(0,+)×(vφ)(x,z).0=(v-\varphi)(\bar{x},\bar{z})=\max_{(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}}(v-\varphi)(x,z)\;.

Let us observe that vφv\leq\varphi by construction. Since vv is continuous, there exists a sequence {(xn,zn)}n1\{(x_{n},z_{n})\}_{n\geq 1} such that

(xn,zn)(x¯,z¯)and v(xn,zn)v(x¯,z¯)as n+.(x_{n},z_{n})\to(\bar{x},\bar{z})\qquad\text{and }\qquad v(x_{n},z_{n})\to v(\bar{x},\bar{z})\qquad\text{as }n\to+\infty\;.

Correspondingly, we must have that

γnv(xn,zn)φ(xn,zn)0as n+.\gamma_{n}\doteq v(x_{n},z_{n})-\varphi(x_{n},z_{n})\to 0\qquad\text{as }n\to+\infty\;.

Now let us consider a control u¯t=u¯\bar{u}_{t}=\bar{u} t>0\forall t>0, for some arbitrary constant u¯[U1,U2]\bar{u}\in[-U_{1},U_{2}]. Moreover, let introduce a sequence of stopping times {τn}n0\{\tau_{n}\}_{n\geq 0} as follows:

τn=inf{s0max{|Xsu¯,xnxn|,|Zsznzn|}>ϵ}hnn1,\tau_{n}=\inf\{s\geq 0\mid\max\{\lvert X^{\bar{u},x_{n}}_{s}-x_{n}\rvert,\lvert Z^{z_{n}}_{s}-z_{n}\rvert\}>\epsilon\}\land h_{n}\qquad n\geq 1\;,

for some fixed ϵ>0\epsilon>0 and {hn}n1\{h_{n}\}_{n\geq 1} such that

hn0,γnhn0as n+.h_{n}\to 0\;,\qquad\frac{\gamma_{n}}{h_{n}}\to 0\qquad\text{as }n\to+\infty\;.

Here {Ztzn}t0\{Z^{z_{n}}_{t}\}_{t\geq 0} denotes the solution of the SDE (2.1) with initial condition Z0zn=znZ^{z_{n}}_{0}=z_{n}. By the dynamic programming principle (see e.g. [16, Theorem 3.3.1]) for any n1n\geq 1 we have that

v(xn,zn)𝔼[0τneλtf(Xtu¯,xn,Ztzn,u¯)𝑑t+eλτnv(Xτnu¯,xn,Zτnzn)],v(x_{n},z_{n})\leq\mathbb{E}\biggl{[}\int_{0}^{\tau_{n}}e^{-\lambda t}f(X^{\bar{u},x_{n}}_{t},Z^{z_{n}}_{t},\bar{u})\,dt+e^{-\lambda\tau_{n}}v(X^{\bar{u},x_{n}}_{\tau_{n}},Z^{z_{n}}_{\tau_{n}})\biggr{]}\;,

hence

φ(xn,zn)+γn𝔼[0τneλtf(Xtu¯,xn,Ztzn,u¯)𝑑t+eλτnφ(Xτnu¯,xn,Zτnzn)].\varphi(x_{n},z_{n})+\gamma_{n}\leq\mathbb{E}\biggl{[}\int_{0}^{\tau_{n}}e^{-\lambda t}f(X^{\bar{u},x_{n}}_{t},Z^{z_{n}}_{t},\bar{u})\,dt+e^{-\lambda\tau_{n}}\varphi(X^{\bar{u},x_{n}}_{\tau_{n}},Z^{z_{n}}_{\tau_{n}})\biggr{]}\;.

Applying Itô’s formula we get that

eλτnφ(Xτnu¯,xn,Zτnzn)=φ(xn,zn)+0τneλt[u¯φ(Xtu¯,xn,Ztzn)λφ(Xtu¯,xn,Ztzn)]𝑑t+Mτn,e^{-\lambda\tau_{n}}\varphi(X^{\bar{u},x_{n}}_{\tau_{n}},Z^{z_{n}}_{\tau_{n}})=\varphi(x_{n},z_{n})+\int_{0}^{\tau_{n}}e^{-\lambda t}[\mathcal{L}^{\bar{u}}\varphi(X^{\bar{u},x_{n}}_{t},Z^{z_{n}}_{t})-\lambda\varphi(X^{\bar{u},x_{n}}_{t},Z^{z_{n}}_{t})]\,dt+M_{\tau_{n}}\;, (5.5)

where

Mt=0teλsφx(Xsu¯,xn,Zszn)σXsu¯,xn𝑑Ws+0teλsφz(Xsu¯,xn,Zszn)σZ(Zszn)𝑑WsZ.M_{t}=\int_{0}^{t}e^{-\lambda s}\frac{\partial{\varphi}}{\partial{x}}(X^{\bar{u},x_{n}}_{s},Z^{z_{n}}_{s})\sigma X^{\bar{u},x_{n}}_{s}\,dW_{s}+\int_{0}^{t}e^{-\lambda s}\frac{\partial{\varphi}}{\partial{z}}(X^{\bar{u},x_{n}}_{s},Z^{z_{n}}_{s})\sigma_{Z}(Z^{z_{n}}_{s})\,dW^{Z}_{s}\;.

Clearly {Mt}t0\{M_{t}\}_{t\geq 0} is a local martingale (having {τn}n0\{\tau_{n}\}_{n\geq 0} as localizing sequence of stopping times) because the integrand functions are continuous and hence bounded on the compact sets. Taking expectations in equation (5.5) and using the previous inequality yields

γn+φ(xn,zn)=γn𝔼[0τneλt[u¯φ(Xtu¯,xn,Ztzn)λφ(Xtu¯,xn,Ztzn)]𝑑t]+𝔼[eλτnφ(Xτnu¯,xn,Zτnzn)]𝔼[0τneλtf(Xtu¯,xn,Ztzn,u¯)𝑑t]+𝔼[eλτnφ(Xτnu¯,xn,Zτnzn)],\begin{split}&\gamma_{n}+\varphi(x_{n},z_{n})\\ &=\gamma_{n}-\mathbb{E}\biggl{[}\int_{0}^{\tau_{n}}e^{-\lambda t}[\mathcal{L}^{\bar{u}}\varphi(X^{\bar{u},x_{n}}_{t},Z^{z_{n}}_{t})-\lambda\varphi(X^{\bar{u},x_{n}}_{t},Z^{z_{n}}_{t})]\,dt\biggr{]}+\mathbb{E}\biggl{[}e^{-\lambda\tau_{n}}\varphi(X^{\bar{u},x_{n}}_{\tau_{n}},Z^{z_{n}}_{\tau_{n}})\biggr{]}\\ &\leq\mathbb{E}\biggl{[}\int_{0}^{\tau_{n}}e^{-\lambda t}f(X^{\bar{u},x_{n}}_{t},Z^{z_{n}}_{t},\bar{u})\,dt\biggr{]}+\mathbb{E}\biggl{[}e^{-\lambda\tau_{n}}\varphi(X^{\bar{u},x_{n}}_{\tau_{n}},Z^{z_{n}}_{\tau_{n}})\biggr{]}\;,\end{split}

that is, dividing by hnh_{n} (using that τnhn\tau_{n}\leq h_{n}),

γnhn𝔼[1hn0τneλt[u¯φ(Xtu¯,xn,Ztzn)+f(Xtu¯,xn,Ztzn,u¯)λφ(Xtu¯,xn,Ztzn)]𝑑t].\frac{\gamma_{n}}{h_{n}}\leq\mathbb{E}\biggl{[}\frac{1}{h_{n}}\int_{0}^{\tau_{n}}e^{-\lambda t}[\mathcal{L}^{\bar{u}}\varphi(X^{\bar{u},x_{n}}_{t},Z^{z_{n}}_{t})+f(X^{\bar{u},x_{n}}_{t},Z^{z_{n}}_{t},\bar{u})-\lambda\varphi(X^{\bar{u},x_{n}}_{t},Z^{z_{n}}_{t})]\,dt\biggr{]}\;.

Letting n+n\to+\infty we have that Xtu¯,xnXtu¯,x¯X^{\bar{u},x_{n}}_{t}\to X^{\bar{u},\bar{x}}_{t} and ZtznZtz¯Z^{z_{n}}_{t}\to Z^{\bar{z}}_{t}, t0\forall t\geq 0 a.s.\mathbb{P}-a.s. and the right-hand side converges to u¯φ(x¯,z¯)+f(x¯,z¯,u¯)λφ(x¯,z¯)\mathcal{L}^{\bar{u}}\varphi(\bar{x},\bar{z})+f(\bar{x},\bar{z},\bar{u})-\lambda\varphi(\bar{x},\bar{z}) by the mean value theorem for integrals. Hence

u¯φ(x¯,z¯)+f(x¯,z¯,u¯)λφ(x¯,z¯)0.\mathcal{L}^{\bar{u}}\varphi(\bar{x},\bar{z})+f(\bar{x},\bar{z},\bar{u})-\lambda\varphi(\bar{x},\bar{z})\geq 0\;.

Since u¯\bar{u} is arbitrary, taking the infimum we obtain that vv is a viscosity subsolution of equation (5.2) (see equation (5.3)).

Now we prove that vv is a viscosity supersolution. To this end, we take a test function φ𝒞2,2((0,+)×)\varphi\in\mathcal{C}^{2,2}((0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}) such that

0=(vφ)(x¯,z¯)=min(x,z)(0,+)×(vφ)(x,z).0=(v-\varphi)(\bar{x},\bar{z})=\min_{(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}}(v-\varphi)(x,z)\;.

By definition of the value function, we can find a strategy {u^t}t0𝒰\{\hat{u}_{t}\}_{t\geq 0}\in\mathcal{U} such that

v(xn,zn)+hn2𝔼[0τneλtf(Xtu^,xn,Ztzn,u^t)𝑑t+eλτnv(Xτnu^,xn,Zτnzn)],v(x_{n},z_{n})+h_{n}^{2}\geq\mathbb{E}\biggl{[}\int_{0}^{\tau_{n}}e^{-\lambda t}f(X^{\hat{u},x_{n}}_{t},Z^{z_{n}}_{t},\hat{u}_{t})\,dt+e^{-\lambda\tau_{n}}v(X^{\hat{u},x_{n}}_{\tau_{n}},Z^{z_{n}}_{\tau_{n}})\biggr{]}\;,

and hence

φ(xn,zn)+γn+hn2𝔼[0τneλtf(Xtu^,xn,Ztzn,u^t)𝑑t+eλτnv(Xτnu^,xn,Zτnzn)].\varphi(x_{n},z_{n})+\gamma_{n}+h_{n}^{2}\geq\mathbb{E}\biggl{[}\int_{0}^{\tau_{n}}e^{-\lambda t}f(X^{\hat{u},x_{n}}_{t},Z^{z_{n}}_{t},\hat{u}_{t})\,dt+e^{-\lambda\tau_{n}}v(X^{\hat{u},x_{n}}_{\tau_{n}},Z^{z_{n}}_{\tau_{n}})\biggr{]}\;.

Using equation (5.5) we obtain that

γn+hn2+𝔼[eλτnφ(Xτnu^,xn,Zτnzn)]𝔼[0τneλt[u^φ(Xtu^,xn,Ztzn)λφ(Xtu^,xn,Ztzn)]𝑑t]𝔼[0τneλtf(Xtu^,xn,Ztzn,u^t)𝑑t]+𝔼[eλτnφ(Xτnu^,xn,Zτnzn)],\gamma_{n}+h_{n}^{2}+\mathbb{E}\biggl{[}e^{-\lambda\tau_{n}}\varphi(X^{\hat{u},x_{n}}_{\tau_{n}},Z^{z_{n}}_{\tau_{n}})\biggr{]}-\mathbb{E}\biggl{[}\int_{0}^{\tau_{n}}e^{-\lambda t}[\mathcal{L}^{\hat{u}}\varphi(X^{\hat{u},x_{n}}_{t},Z^{z_{n}}_{t})-\lambda\varphi(X^{\hat{u},x_{n}}_{t},Z^{z_{n}}_{t})]\,dt\biggr{]}\\ \geq\mathbb{E}\biggl{[}\int_{0}^{\tau_{n}}e^{-\lambda t}f(X^{\hat{u},x_{n}}_{t},Z^{z_{n}}_{t},\hat{u}_{t})\,dt\biggr{]}+\mathbb{E}\biggl{[}e^{-\lambda\tau_{n}}\varphi(X^{\hat{u},x_{n}}_{\tau_{n}},Z^{z_{n}}_{\tau_{n}})\biggr{]}\;,

and dividing by hnh_{n} we get

γnhn+hn𝔼[1hn0τneλt[u^φ(Xtu^,xn,Ztzn)+f(Xtu^,xn,Ztzn,u^t)λφ(Xtu^,xn,Ztzn)]𝑑t]𝔼[1hn0τninfu[U1,U2]{uφ(Xtu,xn,Ztzn)+f(Xtu,xn,Ztzn,u)λφ(Xtu,xn,Ztzn)}dt].\begin{split}\frac{\gamma_{n}}{h_{n}}+h_{n}&\geq\mathbb{E}\biggl{[}\frac{1}{h_{n}}\int_{0}^{\tau_{n}}e^{-\lambda t}[\mathcal{L}^{\hat{u}}\varphi(X^{\hat{u},x_{n}}_{t},Z^{z_{n}}_{t})+f(X^{\hat{u},x_{n}}_{t},Z^{z_{n}}_{t},\hat{u}_{t})-\lambda\varphi(X^{\hat{u},x_{n}}_{t},Z^{z_{n}}_{t})]\,dt\biggr{]}\\ &\geq\mathbb{E}\biggl{[}\frac{1}{h_{n}}\int_{0}^{\tau_{n}}\inf_{u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}]}\{\mathcal{L}^{u}\varphi(X^{u,x_{n}}_{t},Z^{z_{n}}_{t})+f(X^{u,x_{n}}_{t},Z^{z_{n}}_{t},u)-\lambda\varphi(X^{u,x_{n}}_{t},Z^{z_{n}}_{t})\}\,dt\biggr{]}\;.\end{split}

Observing that

limn+τnhn=min{limn+inf{s0max{|Xsu¯,xnxn|,|Zsznzn|}ϵ}hn,1}=1,\lim_{n\to+\infty}\frac{\tau_{n}}{h_{n}}=\min\{\lim_{n\to+\infty}\frac{\inf\{s\geq 0\mid\max\{\lvert X^{\bar{u},x_{n}}_{s}-x_{n}\rvert,\lvert Z^{z_{n}}_{s}-z_{n}\rvert\}\geq\epsilon\}}{h_{n}},1\}=1\;,

using the mean value theorem for integrals again, we finally get the inequality

infu[U1,U2]{uφ(x¯,z¯)+f(x¯,z¯,u)λφ(x¯,z¯)}0,\inf_{u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}]}\{\mathcal{L}^{u}\varphi(\bar{x},\bar{z})+f(\bar{x},\bar{z},u)-\lambda\varphi(\bar{x},\bar{z})\}\leq 0\;,

and hence vv is a viscosity supersolution of equation (5.2) (see equation (5.4)). ∎

Now we provide a Verification Theorem based on classical solutions to the HJB equation (5.2).

Theorem 5.2.

Let w:(0,+)×[0,+)w\colon(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}\to[0,+\infty) be a function in 𝒞2,2((0,+)×)\mathcal{C}^{2,2}((0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}) and suppose that there exists a constant C1>0C_{1}>0 such that

|w(x,z)|C1(1+|x|m)(x,z)(0,+)×.\lvert w(x,z)\rvert\leq C_{1}(1+\lvert x\rvert^{m})\qquad\forall(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}\;.

If

infu[U1,U2]{uw(x,z)+f(x,z,u)λw(x,z)}0(x,z)(0,+)×,\inf_{u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}]}\{\mathcal{L}^{u}w(x,z)+f(x,z,u)-\lambda w(x,z)\}\geq 0\qquad\forall(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}\;, (5.6)

then w(x,z)v(x,z)w(x,z)\leq v(x,z) (x,z)(0,+)×\forall(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}.

Now suppose that there exists a [U1,U2][-U_{1},U_{2}]-valued measurable function u(x,z)u^{*}(x,z) such that

infu[U1,U2]{uw(x,z)+f(x,z,u)λw(x,z)}=uw(x,z)+f(x,z,u(x,z))λw(x,z)=0(x,z)(0,+)×.\inf_{u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}]}\{\mathcal{L}^{u}w(x,z)+f(x,z,u)-\lambda w(x,z)\}\\ =\mathcal{L}^{u^{*}}w(x,z)+f(x,z,u^{*}(x,z))-\lambda w(x,z)=0\quad\forall(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}\;. (5.7)

Then w(x,z)=v(x,z)w(x,z)=v(x,z) (x,z)(0,+)×\forall(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R} and u={u(Xtu,x,Zt)}t0u^{*}=\{u^{*}(X^{u^{*},x}_{t},Z_{t})\}_{t\geq 0} is an optimal (Markovian) control.

Proof.

Let w𝒞2,2((0,+)×)w\in\mathcal{C}^{2,2}((0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}). Let us introduce a sequence of stopping times defined by

τninf{t00te2λs|wx(Xsu,x,Zs)σXsu,x|2𝑑sn}inf{t00te2λs|wz(Xsu,x,Zs)σZ(Zs)|2𝑑sn},n=1,2,.\tau_{n}\doteq\inf\{t\geq 0\mid\int_{0}^{t}e^{-2\lambda s}\left\lvert\frac{\partial{w}}{\partial{x}}(X^{u,x}_{s},Z_{s})\sigma X^{u,x}_{s}\right\rvert^{2}\,ds\geq n\}\\ \land\inf\{t\geq 0\mid\int_{0}^{t}e^{-2\lambda s}\left\lvert\frac{\partial{w}}{\partial{z}}(X^{u,x}_{s},Z_{s})\sigma_{Z}(Z_{s})\right\rvert^{2}\,ds\geq n\}\;,\qquad n=1,2,\dots\;. (5.8)

Applying Itô’s formula to eλtw(Xtu,x,Zt)e^{-\lambda t}w(X^{u,x}_{t},Z_{t}) for any arbitrary u𝒰u\in\mathcal{U} we get

eλTτnw(XTτnu,x,ZTτn)=w(x,z)+0Tτneλt[uw(Xtu,x,Zt)λw(Xtu,x,Zt)]𝑑t+0Tτneλtwx(Xtu,x,Zt)σXtu,x𝑑Wt+0Tτneλtwz(Xtu,x,Zt)σZ(Zt)𝑑WtZ.e^{-\lambda T\land\tau_{n}}w(X^{u,x}_{T\land\tau_{n}},Z_{T\land\tau_{n}})=w(x,z)+\int_{0}^{T\land\tau_{n}}e^{-\lambda t}[\mathcal{L}^{u}w(X^{u,x}_{t},Z_{t})-\lambda w(X^{u,x}_{t},Z_{t})]\,dt\\ +\int_{0}^{T\land\tau_{n}}e^{-\lambda t}\frac{\partial{w}}{\partial{x}}(X^{u,x}_{t},Z_{t})\sigma X^{u,x}_{t}\,dW_{t}+\int_{0}^{T\land\tau_{n}}e^{-\lambda t}\frac{\partial{w}}{\partial{z}}(X^{u,x}_{t},Z_{t})\sigma_{Z}(Z_{t})\,dW^{Z}_{t}\;.

The last integrals are real martingales by definition of τn\tau_{n} (see equation (5.8)), hence taking the expectation and using the inequality (5.6) gives

𝔼[eλTτnw(XTτnu,x,ZTτn)]w(x,z)𝔼[0Tτneλtf(Xtu,x,Zt,ut)𝑑t].\mathbb{E}[e^{-\lambda T\land\tau_{n}}w(X^{u,x}_{T\land\tau_{n}},Z_{T\land\tau_{n}})]\geq w(x,z)-\mathbb{E}\biggl{[}\int_{0}^{T\land\tau_{n}}e^{-\lambda t}f(X^{u,x}_{t},Z_{t},u_{t})\,dt\biggr{]}\;.

By the growth condition on ww and Proposition 3.1 we can apply the dominated convergence theorem, so that letting n+n\to+\infty gives222Notice that τn+\tau_{n}\to+\infty because the integrand functions in equation (5.8) are continuous by our assumptions.

𝔼[eλTw(XTu,x,ZT)]w(x,z)𝔼[0Teλtf(Xtu,x,Zt,ut)𝑑t]u𝒰.\mathbb{E}[e^{-\lambda T}w(X^{u,x}_{T},Z_{T})]\geq w(x,z)-\mathbb{E}\biggl{[}\int_{0}^{T}e^{-\lambda t}f(X^{u,x}_{t},Z_{t},u_{t})\,dt\biggr{]}\qquad\forall u\in\mathcal{U}\;.

Recalling equation (2.9), since

lim supT+eλT𝔼[w(XTu,x,ZT)]C1lim supT+eλT𝔼[1+(XTu,x)m]0(x,z)(0,+)×,u𝒰,\begin{split}\limsup_{T\to+\infty}e^{-\lambda T}\mathbb{E}[w(X^{u,x}_{T},Z_{T})]&\leq C_{1}\limsup_{T\to+\infty}e^{-\lambda T}\mathbb{E}[1+(X^{u,x}_{T})^{m}]\\ &\leq 0\qquad\forall(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R},\forall u\in\mathcal{U}\;,\end{split}

we can send T+T\to+\infty to obtain that

w(x,z)𝔼[0+eλtf(Xtu,x,Zt,ut)𝑑t]u𝒰,w(x,z)\leq\mathbb{E}\biggl{[}\int_{0}^{+\infty}e^{-\lambda t}f(X^{u,x}_{t},Z_{t},u_{t})\,dt\biggr{]}\qquad\forall u\in\mathcal{U}\;,

which implies the first inequality w(x,z)v(x,z)w(x,z)\leq v(x,z) (x,z)(0,+)×\forall(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}.

Now we can repeat the same argument choosing the control {ut=u(Xtu,x,Zt)}t0\{u^{*}_{t}=u^{*}(X^{u^{*},x}_{t},Z_{t})\}_{t\geq 0}, obtaining the equality

𝔼[eλTw(XTu,x,ZT)]=w(x,z)𝔼[0Teλtf(Xtu,x,Zt,ut)𝑑t].\mathbb{E}[e^{-\lambda T}w(X^{u^{*},x}_{T},Z_{T})]=w(x,z)-\mathbb{E}\biggl{[}\int_{0}^{T}e^{-\lambda t}f(X^{u^{*},x}_{t},Z_{t},u^{*}_{t})\,dt\biggr{]}\;.

Using the fact that

lim infT+eλT𝔼[w(XTu,x,ZT)]0(x,z)(0,+)×,\liminf_{T\to+\infty}e^{-\lambda T}\mathbb{E}[w(X^{u^{*},x}_{T},Z_{T})]\geq 0\qquad\forall(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}\;,

sending T+T\to+\infty we deduce

w(x,z)𝔼[0+eλtf(Xtu,x,Zt,u(Xtu,x,Zt))𝑑t],w(x,z)\geq\mathbb{E}\biggl{[}\int_{0}^{+\infty}e^{-\lambda t}f(X^{u^{*},x}_{t},Z_{t},u^{*}(X^{u^{*},x}_{t},Z_{t}))\,dt\biggr{]}\;,

which shows that w(x,z)=v(x,z)w(x,z)=v(x,z) (x,z)(0,+)×\forall(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R} and that uu^{*} is an optimal control. ∎

6.   The optimal fiscal policy

In view of the Verification Theorem in this section we aim at investigating the optimal candidate fiscal policy and its properties. Putting the expression (5.1) into the HJB equation (5.2) and gathering the terms which depend on uu gives

infu[U1,U2]{x[g(z,u)u]vx(x,z)+f(x,z,u)}+xr(z)vx(x,z)+12σ2x22vx2(x,z)+ρσxσZ(z)2vxz(x,z)+Zv(x,z)λv(x,z)=0.\begin{split}&\inf_{u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}]}\{x[-g(z,u)-u]\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)+f(x,z,u)\}+xr(z)\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)\\ &+\frac{1}{2}\sigma^{2}x^{2}\frac{\partial^{2}{v}}{\partial{x^{2}}}(x,z)+\rho\sigma x\sigma_{Z}(z)\frac{\partial^{2}{v}}{\partial{x}\partial{z}}(x,z)+\mathcal{L}^{Z}v(x,z)-\lambda v(x,z)=0\;.\end{split} (6.1)

We look for a minimizer of the following function:

H(x,z,u)=x[g(z,u)+u]vx(x,z)+f(x,z,u).H(x,z,u)=-x[g(z,u)+u]\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)+f(x,z,u)\;. (6.2)

Our candidate optimal strategy is given through a function u:(0,+)×[U1,U2]u^{*}\colon(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}\to[-U_{1},U_{2}] which solves the following minimization problem:

H(x,z,u(x,z))=minu[U1,U2]H(x,z,u).H(x,z,u^{*}(x,z))=\min_{u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}]}H(x,z,u)\;. (6.3)

To this end, we make use of the following assumptions.

Assumption 6.1.

We assume that

  • gg is continuous and differentiable in u[U1,U2]u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}];

  • ff is continuous and differentiable in u[U1,U2]u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}];

  • vC2,2((0,+)×)v\in C^{2,2}((0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}) is a classical solution of equation (6.1).

We first state the existence and uniqueness of the minimizer of problem (6.3), then we give a characterization of it.

Proposition 6.1.

The problem (6.3) admits a minimizer u(x,z)[U1,U2]u^{*}(x,z)\in[-U_{1},U_{2}] for any (x,z)(0,+)×(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}. Moreover, if HH is strictly convex, the minimizer is also unique.

Proof.

The existence of a minimizer immediately follows by the compactness of the interval [U1,U2][-U_{1},U_{2}] and the Weierstrass Theorem. Moreover, the strictly convexity of HH implies the uniqueness of the minimizer by classical arguments. ∎

Remark 6.1.

If ff and gg are both linear on u[U1,U2]u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}], H(x,z,u)H(x,z,u) is linear and the minimizer is also unique.

Proposition 6.2.

Suppose that 2Hu2(x,z,u)>0\frac{\partial^{2}{H}}{\partial{u}^{2}}(x,z,u)>0, (x,z,u)(0,+)×[U1,U2]\forall(x,z,u)(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}\in[-U_{1},U_{2}]. Then there exists a unique minimizer u(x,z)u^{*}(x,z) for the problem (6.3). Moreover, u(x,z)u^{*}(x,z) admits the following expression:

u(x,z)={U1(x,z){(x,z)(0,+)×fu(x,z,U1)xvx(x,z)[gu(z,U1)+1]}U2(x,z){(x,z)(0,+)×fu(x,z,U2)xvx(x,z)[gu(z,U2)+1]}u^(x,z)otherwise,u^{*}(x,z)=\\ \begin{cases}-U_{1}&(x,z)\in\Set{(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}\mid\frac{\partial{f}}{\partial{u}}(x,z,-U_{1})\geq x\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)\bigl{[}\frac{\partial{g}}{\partial{u}}(z,-U_{1})+1\bigr{]}}\\ U_{2}&(x,z)\in\Set{(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}\mid\frac{\partial{f}}{\partial{u}}(x,z,U_{2})\leq x\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)\bigl{[}\frac{\partial{g}}{\partial{u}}(z,U_{2})+1\bigr{]}}\\ \hat{u}(x,z)&\text{otherwise}\;,\end{cases}

where u^(x,z)\hat{u}(x,z) denotes the solution to

xvx(x,z)[gu(z,u)+1]=fu(x,z,u)(x,z)(0,+)×.x\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)\biggl{[}\frac{\partial{g}}{\partial{u}}(z,u)+1\biggr{]}=\frac{\partial{f}}{\partial{u}}(x,z,u)\quad\forall(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}\;. (6.4)
Proof.

Existence and uniqueness of the minimizer are guaranteed by classical arguments, since HH is continuous and strictly convex in u[U1,U2]u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}]. Observing that

Hu(x,z,u)=fu(x,z,u)xvx(x,z)[gu(z,u)+1],\frac{\partial{H}}{\partial{u}}(x,z,u)=\frac{\partial{f}}{\partial{u}}(x,z,u)-x\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)\biggl{[}\frac{\partial{g}}{\partial{u}}(z,u)+1\biggr{]}\;, (6.5)

we have only three cases.

  1. 1.

    If (x,z)(0,+)×(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R} are such that Hu(x,z,U1)0\frac{\partial{H}}{\partial{u}}(x,z,-U_{1})\geq 0, i.e.

    fu(x,z,U1)xvx(x,z)[gu(z,U1)+1],\frac{\partial{f}}{\partial{u}}(x,z,-U_{1})\geq x\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)\bigl{[}\frac{\partial{g}}{\partial{u}}(z,-U_{1})+1\bigr{]}\;,

    then we must have

    Hu(x,z,u)Hu(x,z,U1)0u[U1,U2],\frac{\partial{H}}{\partial{u}}(x,z,u)\geq\frac{\partial{H}}{\partial{u}}(x,z,-U_{1})\geq 0\qquad\forall u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}]\;,

    because of the convexity of HH. Hence HH is increasing on the whole interval [U1,U2][-U_{1},U_{2}] and the minimizer turns out to be u(x,z)=U1u^{*}(x,z)=-U_{1}.

  2. 2.

    If (x,z)(0,+)×(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R} are such that Hu(x,z,U2)0\frac{\partial{H}}{\partial{u}}(x,z,U_{2})\leq 0, i.e.

    fu(x,z,U2)xvx(x,z)[gu(z,U2)+1],\frac{\partial{f}}{\partial{u}}(x,z,U_{2})\leq x\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)\bigl{[}\frac{\partial{g}}{\partial{u}}(z,U_{2})+1\bigr{]}\;,

    then we have that

    Hu(x,z,u)Hu(x,z,U2)0u[U1,U2],\frac{\partial{H}}{\partial{u}}(x,z,u)\leq\frac{\partial{H}}{\partial{u}}(x,z,U_{2})\leq 0\qquad\forall u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}]\;,

    so that HH is decreasing in u[U1,U2]u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}] and therefore u(x,z)=U2u^{*}(x,z)=U_{2} is the minimizer.

  3. 3.

    Finally, when Hu(x,z,U1)<0\frac{\partial{H}}{\partial{u}}(x,z,-U_{1})<0 and Hu(x,z,U2)>0\frac{\partial{H}}{\partial{u}}(x,z,U_{2})>0, since Hu\frac{\partial{H}}{\partial{u}} is continuous in u[U1,U2]u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}], there exists u^(x,z)\hat{u}(x,z) such that Hu(x,z,u^(x,z))=0\frac{\partial{H}}{\partial{u}}(x,z,\hat{u}(x,z))=0 (see equation (6.4)) and this stationary point coincides with the minimizer.

6.1.   Some special cases

In this section we investigate some cases of interest. Let us first establish a slightly general result, when the cost function does not depend explicitly on uu.

Proposition 6.3.

Suppose that the cost function ff does not depend on uu, i.e. f(x,z,u)=f(x,z)f(x,z,u)=f(x,z) and 2Hu2(x,z,u)>0\frac{\partial^{2}{H}}{\partial{u}^{2}}(x,z,u)>0, (x,z,u)(0,+)×[U1,U2]\forall(x,z,u)(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}\in[-U_{1},U_{2}]. Then the minimizer of (6.3) is given by

u(x,z)={U1(x,z){(x,z)(0,+)×0vx(x,z)[gu(z,U1)+1]}U2(x,z){(x,z)(0,+)×0vx(x,z)[gu(z,U2)+1]}u^(z)otherwise,u^{*}(x,z)=\begin{cases}-U_{1}&(x,z)\in\Set{(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}\mid 0\geq\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)\bigl{[}\frac{\partial{g}}{\partial{u}}(z,-U_{1})+1\bigr{]}}\\ U_{2}&(x,z)\in\Set{(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}\mid 0\leq\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)\bigl{[}\frac{\partial{g}}{\partial{u}}(z,U_{2})+1\bigr{]}}\\ \hat{u}(z)&\text{otherwise}\;,\end{cases} (6.6)

where u^(z)\hat{u}(z) is the unique solution to

gu(z,u)=1z.\frac{\partial{g}}{\partial{u}}(z,u)=-1\quad\forall z\in\mathbb{R}\;. (6.7)
Proof.

Observing that

Hu(x,z,u)=xvx(x,z)[gu(z,u)+1],\frac{\partial{H}}{\partial{u}}(x,z,u)=-x\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)\biggl{[}\frac{\partial{g}}{\partial{u}}(z,u)+1\biggr{]}\;, (6.8)
2Hu2(x,z,u)=xvx(x,z)2gu2(z,u)>0,\frac{\partial^{2}{H}}{\partial{u}^{2}}(x,z,u)=-x\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)\frac{\partial^{2}{g}}{\partial{u}^{2}}(z,u)>0\;, (6.9)

hence vx(x,z)0\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)\neq 0, (x,z)(0,+)×\forall(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R} and the proof follows the same lines of Proposition 6.2. ∎

The result of Proposition 6.3 is interesting. When the fiscal policy has a nonlinear impact on GDP growth, the government will select the primary surplus in order that the effect on GDP matches that on debt, in general (see equation (6.7)). When this is not possible, the extreme policies are chosen. The choice between U1-U_{1} and U2U_{2} and the corresponding economic interpretation crucially depend on the government objective, see the comments below Proposition 6.5.

In the case of Example 2.1, that is when the fiscal policy has a linear impact on the GDP growth rate, (see equation (2.5)), Proposition 6.3 does not apply, because the condition 2Hu2(x,z,u)>0\frac{\partial^{2}{H}}{\partial{u}^{2}}(x,z,u)>0, (x,z,u)(0,+)×[U1,U2]\forall(x,z,u)(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}\in[-U_{1},U_{2}] is not fulfilled. In the next proposition we discuss a tailor-made result for this special case.

Proposition 6.4.

Suppose that the cost function ff does not depend on uu, i.e. f(x,z,u)=f(x,z)f(x,z,u)=f(x,z) and let the GDP growth rate given by

g(z,u)=g0(z)α(z)u,g(z,u)=g_{0}(z)-\alpha(z)u\;,

with g0:g_{0}\colon\mathbb{R}\to\mathbb{R} and α(z)>0\alpha(z)>0, α(z)1\alpha(z)\neq 1, z\forall z\in\mathbb{R}. Then the minimizer of (6.3) is given by

u(x,z)={U1(x,z){(x,z)(0,+)×vx(x,z)(α(z)1)0]}U2(x,z){(x,z)(0,+)×vx(x,z)(α(z)1)<0]}.u^{*}(x,z)=\begin{cases}-U_{1}&(x,z)\in\Set{(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}\mid\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)(\alpha(z)-1)\geq 0\bigr{]}}\\ U_{2}&(x,z)\in\Set{(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}\mid\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)(\alpha(z)-1)<0\bigr{]}}.\end{cases} (6.10)
Proof.

The statement follows by observing that HH is a linear function on u[U1,U2]u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}]

H(x,z,u)=x[g0(z)+(1α(z))u]vx(x,z)+f(x,z).H(x,z,u)=-x[g_{0}(z)+(1-\alpha(z))u]\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)+f(x,z)\;.

In the next proposition we discuss the case where the cost function f(x,z)f(x,z) does not depend on uu and it is increasing in x(0,+)x\in(0,+\infty). This situation refers to the case where debt generates a disutility for the government of the country and thus it aims to reduce the debt-to-GDP ratio. We refer to this case as the debt reduction problem, see Section 7.1.

Proposition 6.5.

Suppose that the cost function ff does not depend on uu, i.e. f(x,z,u)=f(x,z)f(x,z,u)=f(x,z), with f(x,z)f(x,z) increasing in x(0,+)x\in(0,+\infty). Assuming vx(x,z)0\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)\neq 0 for any (x,z)(0,+)×(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R} and 2gu2(z,u)<0\frac{\partial^{2}{g}}{\partial{u}^{2}}(z,u)<0 for any (z,u)×[U1,U2](z,u)\in\mathbb{R}\times[-U_{1},U_{2}], the unique minimizer of (6.3) is given by

u(z)=U1u^(z)U2,u^{*}(z)=-U_{1}\lor\hat{u}(z)\land U_{2}\;,

where u^(z)\hat{u}(z) is the unique solution to

gu(z,u)=1,z.\frac{\partial{g}}{\partial{u}}(z,u)=-1,\quad\forall z\in\mathbb{R}\;.

Precisely, u(z)u^{*}(z) admits the following structure:

u(z)={U1z{zgu(z,U1)<1}U2z{zgu(z,U2)>1}u^(z)otherwise.u^{*}(z)=\begin{cases}-U_{1}&z\in\Set{z\in\mathbb{R}\mid\frac{\partial{g}}{\partial{u}}(z,-U_{1})<-1}\\ U_{2}&z\in\Set{z\in\mathbb{R}\mid\frac{\partial{g}}{\partial{u}}(z,U_{2})>-1}\\ \hat{u}(z)&\text{otherwise}\;.\end{cases} (6.11)
Proof.

By Proposition 4.2 we have that v(x,z)v(x,z) is increasing in x(0,+)x\in(0,+\infty) for any zz\in\mathbb{R}, hence vx(x,z)0\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)\geq 0, z\forall z\in\mathbb{R}, which together with the assumptions vx(x,z)0\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)\neq 0, for any (x,z)(0,+)×(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R} and 2gu2(z,u)<0\frac{\partial^{2}{g}}{\partial{u}^{2}}(z,u)<0 for any (z,u)×[U1,U2](z,u)\in\mathbb{R}\times[-U_{1},U_{2}] imply

2Hu2(x,z,u)=xvx(x,z)2gu2(z,u)>0(x,z,u)(0,+)××[U1,U2].\frac{\partial^{2}{H}}{\partial{u}^{2}}(x,z,u)=-x\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)\frac{\partial^{2}{g}}{\partial{u}^{2}}(z,u)>0\quad\forall(x,z,u)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}\times[-U_{1},U_{2}]\;.

Recalling that

Hu(x,z,u)=xvx(x,z)[gu(z,u)+1],\frac{\partial{H}}{\partial{u}}(x,z,u)=-x\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)\biggl{[}\frac{\partial{g}}{\partial{u}}(z,u)+1\biggr{]}\;,

the first order condition reads as if and only if

gu(z,u)+1=0,\frac{\partial{g}}{\partial{u}}(z,u)+1=0\;,

and the proof follows the same lines of Proposition 6.2. ∎

The previous result has an intermediate case as in Proposition 6.3, with the same interpretation. However, as announced, now we can provide a deeper insights on extreme fiscal policies.
The maximum surplus will be applied only if the beneficial impact on debt more than compensates the negative effect on GDP growth. Indeed, the marginal impact of U2U_{2} on the GDP growth is measured by gu(z,U1)\frac{\partial{g}}{\partial{u}}(z,-U_{1}), which is negative, while the effect on debt is unitary. When the debt can be decreased more than the GDP growth by means of the maximum surplus, U2U_{2} is optimal. Similarly, the maximum deficit is chosen when the positive effect on GDP exceeds the negative effect on debt.

In the case of Example 2.1, that is when the fiscal policy has a linear impact on the GDP growth rate, (see equation (2.5)) we have an analogous result.

Proposition 6.6.

Let the GDP growth rate given by

g(z,u)=g0(z)α(z)u,g(z,u)=g_{0}(z)-\alpha(z)u\;,

with g0:g_{0}\colon\mathbb{R}\to\mathbb{R} and α(z)>0\alpha(z)>0, α(z)1\alpha(z)\neq 1, z\forall z\in\mathbb{R}. Then for any running cost function f(x,z)f(x,z) with f(x,z)f(x,z) increasing in x(0,+)x\in(0,+\infty) z\forall z\in\mathbb{R}, assuming vx(x,z)0\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)\neq 0, for any (x,z)(0,+)×(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}, the unique minimizer of (6.3) is given by

u(z)={U1z{zα(z)>1}U2z{zα(z)<1}.u^{*}(z)=\begin{cases}-U_{1}&z\in\Set{z\in\mathbb{R}\mid\alpha(z)>1}\\ U_{2}&z\in\Set{z\in\mathbb{R}\mid\alpha(z)<1}\;.\end{cases} (6.12)
Proof.

Observing that

H(x,z,u)=x[g0(z)+(1α(z))u]vx(x,z)+f(x,z),H(x,z,u)=-x[g_{0}(z)+(1-\alpha(z))u]\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)+f(x,z)\;,

we have only two cases.

  1. 1.

    If z{zα(z)>1}z\in\Set{z\in\mathbb{R}\mid\alpha(z)>1} then HH is increasing in u[U1,U2]u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}] thus the minimizer is u(z)=U1u^{*}(z)=-U_{1}.

  2. 2.

    If z{z0<α(z)<1}z\in\Set{z\in\mathbb{R}\mid 0<\alpha(z)<1} then HH is decreasing in u[U1,U2]u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}] thus the minimizer is u(z)=U2u^{*}(z)=U_{2}.

In the semplified model of equation (2.6), that is when α(z)=α\alpha(z)=\alpha z\forall z\in\mathbb{R}, we have the following result.

Corollary 6.1.

Let the GDP growth rate be given by

g(z,u)=g0(z)αu,g(z,u)=g_{0}(z)-\alpha u\;,

with g0:g_{0}\colon\mathbb{R}\to\mathbb{R} and α>0\alpha>0, α1\alpha\neq 1. Then for any running cost function f(x,z)f(x,z) increasing in x(0,+)x\in(0,+\infty) z\forall z\in\mathbb{R}, assuming vx(x,z)0\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)\neq 0 for any (x,z)(0,+)×(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}, the unique minimizer of (6.3) is constant and given by

u={U1if α>1U2if 0<α<1.u^{*}=\begin{cases}-U_{1}&\text{if }\alpha>1\\ U_{2}&\text{if }0<\alpha<1\;.\end{cases}
Proof.

This is a simple application of Proposition 6.6. ∎

Remark 6.2.

If α>1\alpha>1 we get that the candidate optimal strategy is u=U1u^{*}=-U_{1}, that is the optimal choice for the government is to generate the maximum deficit. Indeed, the beneficial effect on GDP exceeds the debt increase. By Remark 2.3 this strategy is sustainable if

U1>minzg0(z)α1.U_{1}>-{\min_{z\in\mathbb{R}}g_{0}(z)\over\alpha-1}.

It would be natural to assume that minzg0(z)<0\min_{z\in\mathbb{R}}g_{0}(z)<0, and hence the right hand side is positive. Then u=U1u^{*}=-U_{1} would be sustainable if the government can produce enough deficit, which is usually the case.
Conversely, if 0<α<1\ 0<\alpha<1, the candidate optimal strategy is u=U2u^{*}=U_{2}, that is the maximum surplus. By Remark 2.3 this strategy is sustainable if

U2>minzg0(z)1α.U_{2}>-{\min_{z\in\mathbb{R}}g_{0}(z)\over 1-\alpha}\;.

If minzg0(z)<0\min_{z\in\mathbb{R}}g_{0}(z)<0, the optimal policy u=U2u^{*}=U_{2} will be sustainable only if the government has the possibility of increasing taxes and reducing public spending more than a given threshold. In some cases, this could be a challenging task for the government.
Clearly, when minzg0(z)>0\min_{z\in\mathbb{R}}g_{0}(z)>0, the optimal strategy is always sustainable.

Remark 6.3.

Propositions 6.5, 6.6 and Corollary 6.1 show that in the case where f(x,z,u)=f(x,z)f(x,z,u)=f(x,z) is increasing in x(0,+)x\in(0,+\infty),z\forall z\in\mathbb{R}, the minimizer of (6.3) does not depend on the form of the cost function but only on the function g(z,u)g(z,u) which describes the GDP growth rate and the effect of the government policy on it. Thus, given the unitary impact of the fiscal policy on the public debt, the debt-GDP reduction is driven by the effect on the GDP growth rate, which should be the focus of the government attention.

7.   Explicit solutions for some cases of interest

In this section we discuss two examples which can be solved applying the Verification Theorem. In the first example we have in mind a country with debt problems, aiming to reduce its debt ratio. In the second application we discuss the debt smoothing problem, that is, the government wishes to smooth the public debt by flattening its deviation from a given threshold. In the first case the running cost is increasing w.r.t. x(0,+)x\in(0,+\infty), while in the second case we do not require a monotonic condition.

7.1.   The debt reduction problem

We assume that the cost function is given by

f(x,z)=C(z)xm,m2,f(x,z)=C(z)x^{m},\quad m\geq 2\;, (7.1)

where C:[0,+)C\colon\mathbb{R}\to[0,+\infty) is a bounded function. This disutility function generalizes the quadratic function that is widely used in Economics. The parameter mm represents the aversion of the government towards holding debt and the importance of debt for the government is modulated by the function C(z)C(z), which is a function of the values of the environment stochastic factor ZZ.

For instance, if ZZ is an indicator of macroeconomic conditions and higher values correspond to better conditions, assuming that CC is increasing enables the government to relax fiscal rules and debt reduction goals when a massive government intervention is needed, as during economic crises. That is, C(z)C(z) allows for countercyclical policies.

Denoting by

G(z)=infu[U1,U2]{(g(z,u)+u)},G(z)=\inf_{u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}]}\{-(g(z,u)+u)\}\;,

the HJB equation (6.1) reads as

(G(z)+r(z))xvx(x,z)+f(x,z)+12σ2x22vx2(x,z)+ρσxσZ(z)2vxz(x,z)+bZ(z)vz(x,z)+12σZ(z)22vz2(x,z)λv(x,z)=0.\begin{split}&(G(z)+r(z))x\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)+f(x,z)+\frac{1}{2}\sigma^{2}x^{2}\frac{\partial^{2}{v}}{\partial{x^{2}}}(x,z)\\ &+\rho\sigma x\sigma_{Z}(z)\frac{\partial^{2}{v}}{\partial{x}\partial{z}}(x,z)+b_{Z}(z)\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{z}}(x,z)+\frac{1}{2}\sigma_{Z}(z)^{2}\frac{\partial^{2}{v}}{\partial{z^{2}}}(x,z)-\lambda v(x,z)=0\;.\end{split}

With the ansatz v(x,z)=ϕ(z)xmv(x,z)=\phi(z)x^{m} this equation reduces to the following ordinary differential equation (ODE)

12σZ2(z)ϕ′′(z)+(bZ(z)+ρσσZ(z)m)ϕ(z)+[(G(z)+r(z))mλ+σ22m(m1)]ϕ(z)+C(z)=0.\begin{split}&\frac{1}{2}\sigma_{Z}^{2}(z)\phi^{\prime\prime}(z)+(b_{Z}(z)+\rho\sigma\sigma_{Z}(z)m)\phi^{\prime}(z)\\ &+[(G(z)+r(z))m-\lambda+\frac{\sigma^{2}}{2}m(m-1)]\phi(z)+C(z)=0\;.\end{split} (7.2)

We have the following verification result.

Proposition 7.1.

Let us assume there exists a strictly positive and bounded solution ϕC2()\phi\in C^{2}(\mathbb{R}) to equation(LABEL:ODE). Then the value function is given by v(x,z)=ϕ(z)xmC2,2((0,+)×)v(x,z)=\phi(z)x^{m}\in C^{2,2}((0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}). Moreover, assuming 2gu2(z,u)<0\frac{\partial^{2}{g}}{\partial{u}^{2}}(z,u)<0 for any (z,u)×[U1,U2](z,u)\in\mathbb{R}\times[-U_{1},U_{2}] (or gg satisfying (2.5)) then u={u(Zt)}t0u^{*}=\{u^{*}(Z_{t})\}_{t\geq 0} with u(z)u^{*}(z) given in (6.11) ((6.12), respectively) is an optimal strategy.

Proof.

The thesis follows by Theorem 5.2 and Proposition 6.5 (Proposition 6.6, respectively) observing that vx(x,z)=(m1)ϕ(z)xm1>0\frac{\partial{v}}{\partial{x}}(x,z)=(m-1)\phi(z)x^{m-1}>0, (x,z)(0,+)×\forall(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R}. ∎

In order to obtain an explicit formula for the value function we discuss in next example the simplified case without the presence of the stochastic factor ZZ.

Example 7.1.

Let us assume r(z)=rr(z)=r, g(z,u)=g(u)g(z,u)=g(u), σZ=bZ=0\sigma_{Z}=b_{Z}=0, C(z)=C>0C(z)=C>0, hence G(z)=G=infu[U1,U2]{(g(u)+u)}G(z)=G=\inf_{u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}]}\{-(g(u)+u)\} and the HJB reads as

(G+r)xv(x)+Cxm+12σ2x2v′′(x)λv(x)=0.(G+r)xv^{\prime}(x)+Cx^{m}+\frac{1}{2}\sigma^{2}x^{2}v^{\prime\prime}(x)-\lambda v(x)=0\;. (7.3)

It is easy to find an explicit solution to this equation and by the Verification Theorem 5.2 we get that the value function is given by v(x)=kxmv(x)=kx^{m}, with

k=Cλ(G+r)m12m(m1)σ2>0.k=\frac{C}{\lambda-(G+r)m-\frac{1}{2}m(m-1)\sigma^{2}}>0\;.

As observed in Remark 6.3, we get that the optimal strategy depends only on the form of the function g(u)g(u). We discuss below three cases.

  1. 1.

    If g′′(u)<0g^{\prime\prime}(u)<0 u[U1,U2]\forall u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}], then by Proposition 6.5 the optimal control u=U1u^U2u^{*}=-U_{1}\lor\hat{u}\land U_{2} where u^\hat{u} the unique solution to g(u)=1g^{\prime}(u)=-1 and precisely is given by

    u={U1ifg(U1)<1U2ifg(U2)>1u^otherwise.u^{*}=\begin{cases}-U_{1}&\text{if}\;g^{\prime}(-U_{1})<-1\\ U_{2}&\text{if}\;g^{\prime}(U_{2})>-1\\ \hat{u}&\text{otherwise}\;.\end{cases} (7.4)
  2. 2.

    In the case of (2.6), g(u)=g0αug(u)=g_{0}-\alpha u, the optimal strategy is given by

    u={U1ifα>1U2if 0<α<1.u^{*}=\begin{cases}-U_{1}&\text{if}\;\alpha>1\\ U_{2}&\text{if}\;0<\alpha<1\;.\end{cases} (7.5)

    The considerations in Remark 6.2 apply and the optimal strategy is sustainable, when α>1\alpha>1 if U1>g0α1U_{1}>-{g_{0}\over\alpha-1} and when 0<α<10<\alpha<1 if U2>g01αU_{2}>-{g_{0}\over 1-\alpha}.

  3. 3.

    g(u)=g0g(u)=g_{0}, that is the GDP growth rate is not influenced by the fiscal policy, then the optimal strategy u=U2u^{*}=U_{2} (the government apply the maximum level of surplus) and it is sustainable if U2>g0U_{2}>-g_{0}.

7.2.   Debt smoothing

In the previous section we assumed that a cost is associated to any increase of debt, because the aim was to reduce debt. However, in some cases an increase of debt could be more beneficial than its reduction. In [15] there is a noteworthy discussion of this topic, focusing on the trade-off between lowering public debt and building public infrastructure. Clearly, the latter should be the greater priority for countries with low debt and big infrastructure needs. Also, there are some unclear cases with high debt, no plausible risk of fiscal distress and some infrastructure needs. In these cases the optimal debt level is unclear, but sometimes the benefit from increasing debt could surpass the advantages of debt reduction. This is even more true at the current juncture, given the very low level of real interest rates and the existence of demand shortfalls.
Another reason for the government to not let the public debt fall down to zero is related to the role of debt as savings absorber, see [9]. The government wishes to guarantee at any time a given amount of bonds in order to absorb the private savings in the financial market.
Finally, it is well known that sudden and large shocks such as economic crises, wars or pandemics might cause spikes of public debt. “In developed countries […] the aim of debt management was to smooth as much as possible the impact of such temporary expenditure shocks that were initially financed by raising debt” (see [7]).

In this section we address the debt smoothing problem. We assume that the government wishes to smooth the public debt by flattening its deviation from a given threshold x¯>0\bar{x}>0. Hence the cost is represented by the (quadratic) distance between the current debt and the target debt x¯\bar{x}. Formally, we assume that the cost function is given by

f(x)=(xx¯)2.f(x)=(x-\bar{x})^{2}\;. (7.6)

Recalling Proposition 4.1 and Proposition 4.4, we can derive the following properties of the value function v(x,z)v(x,z):

  • v(x,z)0v(x,z)\geq 0, (x,z)(0,+)×\forall(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R} ;

  • v(x,z)v(x,z) is convex w.r.t x(0,+)x\in(0,+\infty) z\forall z\in\mathbb{R} ;

  • v(x,z)x2λλ2+x¯2λv(x,z)\leq{x^{2}\over\lambda-\lambda_{2}}+{\bar{x}^{2}\over\lambda} (x,z)(0,+)×\forall(x,z)\in(0,+\infty)\times\mathbb{R} ;

  • limx0+v(x,z)x¯2λ\lim_{x\to 0^{+}}v(x,z)\leq{\bar{x}^{2}\over\lambda} z\forall z\in\mathbb{R}.

In order to provide an explicit solution to the HJB equation we discuss the simplified case without the stochastic factor. Precisely, we assume σZ=bZ=0\sigma_{Z}=b_{Z}=0, r(z)=rr(z)=r and g(z,u)=g(u)g(z,u)=g(u). Then we denote G1=minu[U1,U2]{(g(u)+u)}G_{1}=min_{u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}]}\{-(g(u)+u)\} and G2=maxu[U1,U2]{(g(u)+u)}G_{2}=max_{u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}]}\{-(g(u)+u)\}, thus the HJB (6.2) reads as

(G1+r)xv(x)+(xx¯)2+12σ2x2v′′(x)λv(x)=0,(G_{1}+r)xv^{\prime}(x)+(x-\bar{x})^{2}+\frac{1}{2}\sigma^{2}x^{2}v^{\prime\prime}(x)-\lambda v(x)=0\;, (7.7)

for v(x)0v^{\prime}(x)\geq 0, and

(G2+r)xv(x)+(xx¯)2+12σ2x2v′′(x)λv(x)=0,(G_{2}+r)xv^{\prime}(x)+(x-\bar{x})^{2}+\frac{1}{2}\sigma^{2}x^{2}v^{\prime\prime}(x)-\lambda v(x)=0\;, (7.8)

for v(x)<0v^{\prime}(x)<0. Recalling that vv^{\prime} is increasing (because vv is convex), we conjecture that there exists a threshold x~>0\widetilde{x}>0 such that v(x)>0v^{\prime}(x)>0 x>x~\forall x>\widetilde{x} and v(x)<0v^{\prime}(x)<0 x<x~\forall x<\widetilde{x}, so that we make the following ansatz:

v(x)={a1x2+b1x+c1+d1xγ1,ifxx~a2x2+b2x+c2+d2xγ2,ifx<x~.v(x)=\begin{cases}a_{1}x^{2}+b_{1}x+c_{1}+d_{1}x^{\gamma_{1}},&\text{if}\;x\geq\widetilde{x}\\ a_{2}x^{2}+b_{2}x+c_{2}+d_{2}x^{\gamma_{2}},&\text{if}\;x<\widetilde{x}\;.\end{cases} (7.9)

By substituting this expression in the equations (7.7) and (7.8) above, we get that

ai=1λ2(Gi+r)σ2,bi=2x¯Gi+rλ,ci=x¯2λ,i=1,2,a_{i}={1\over\lambda-2(G_{i}+r)-\sigma^{2}},\;b_{i}={2\bar{x}\over G_{i}+r-\lambda},\;c_{i}={\bar{x}^{2}\over\lambda},\;i=1,2\;, (7.10)
γ1=[2(G1+r)σ2][2(G1+r)σ2]2+4λσ22σ2<0,\gamma_{1}={-[2(G_{1}+r)-\sigma^{2}]-\sqrt{[2(G_{1}+r)-\sigma^{2}]^{2}+4\lambda\sigma^{2}}\over 2\sigma^{2}}<0\;, (7.11)
γ2=[2(G2+r)σ2]+[2(G2+r)σ2]2+4λσ22σ2>0.\gamma_{2}={-[2(G_{2}+r)-\sigma^{2}]+\sqrt{[2(G_{2}+r)-\sigma^{2}]^{2}+4\lambda\sigma^{2}}\over 2\sigma^{2}}>0\;. (7.12)

Condition (7.11) guarantees the quadratic growth, that is v(x)C(1+x2)v(x)\leq C(1+x^{2}) x(0,+)\forall x\in(0,+\infty), while condition (7.12) implies that limx0+v(x)=x¯2λ\lim_{x\to 0^{+}}v(x)={\bar{x}^{2}\over\lambda}.

We also conjecture that vv is twice continuously differentiable. Then the three constants di,i=1,2d_{i},i=1,2 and x~\widetilde{x} can be found by taking the following conditions into account:

  1. 1.

    v(x~+)=v(x~)v(\widetilde{x}^{+})=v(\widetilde{x}^{-});

  2. 2.

    v(x~+)=v(x~)v^{\prime}(\widetilde{x}^{+})=v^{\prime}(\widetilde{x}^{-});

  3. 3.

    v′′(x~+)=v′′(x~)v^{\prime\prime}(\widetilde{x}^{+})=v^{\prime\prime}(\widetilde{x}^{-}).

In view of (7.9) these equations read as:

  1. 1.

    a1x~2+b1x~+d1x~γ1=a2x~2+b2x~+d2x~γ2a_{1}\widetilde{x}^{2}+b_{1}\widetilde{x}+d_{1}\widetilde{x}^{\gamma_{1}}=a_{2}\widetilde{x}^{2}+b_{2}\widetilde{x}+d_{2}\widetilde{x}^{\gamma_{2}};

  2. 2.

    2a1x~+b1+γ1d1x~γ11=2a2x~+b2+d2γ2x~γ21=02a_{1}\widetilde{x}+b_{1}+\gamma_{1}d_{1}\widetilde{x}^{\gamma_{1}-1}=2a_{2}\widetilde{x}+b_{2}+d_{2}\gamma_{2}\widetilde{x}^{\gamma_{2}-1}=0;

  3. 3.

    2a1+γ1(γ11)d1x~γ12=2a2+d2γ2(γ21)x~γ222a_{1}+\gamma_{1}(\gamma_{1}-1)d_{1}\widetilde{x}^{\gamma_{1}-2}=2a_{2}+d_{2}\gamma_{2}(\gamma_{2}-1)\widetilde{x}^{\gamma_{2}-2}.

Conditions 2 and 3 are equivalent to

d1=d1(x~)=2a1x~+b1γ1x~γ11d_{1}=d_{1}(\widetilde{x})=-{2a_{1}\widetilde{x}+b_{1}\over\gamma_{1}\widetilde{x}^{\gamma_{1}-1}} (7.13)

and

d2=d2(x~)=2(a1a2)x~(γ11)(2a1x~+b1)γ2(γ21)x~γ23,d_{2}=d_{2}(\widetilde{x})={2(a_{1}-a_{2})\widetilde{x}-(\gamma_{1}-1)(2a_{1}\widetilde{x}+b_{1})\over\gamma_{2}(\gamma_{2}-1)\widetilde{x}^{\gamma_{2}-3}}\;, (7.14)

respectively. Then the equation of item 1 can be rewritten as

a1x~2+b1x~+d1(x~)x~γ1=a2x~2+b2x~+d2(x~)x~γ2.a_{1}\widetilde{x}^{2}+b_{1}\widetilde{x}+d_{1}(\widetilde{x})\widetilde{x}^{\gamma_{1}}=a_{2}\widetilde{x}^{2}+b_{2}\widetilde{x}+d_{2}(\widetilde{x})\widetilde{x}^{\gamma_{2}}\;. (7.15)

Clearly, we first need to compute x~\widetilde{x} by solving numerically equation (7.15), then we obtain d1d_{1} and d2d_{2} by equations (7.13) and (7.14), respectively.

Applying the Verification Theorem 5.2 we obtain the following result.

Proposition 7.2.

Let aia_{i}, bib_{i}, cic_{i}, γi\gamma_{i}, i=1,2i=1,2 given in equations (7.10) - (7.11) - (7.12), x~(0,+)\widetilde{x}\in(0,+\infty) solution to equation (7.15), and d1d_{1} and d2d_{2} two constants determined by (7.13) and (7.14), respectively. Define

w(x)={a1x2+b1x+c1+d1xγ1,ifxx~a2x2+b2x+c2+d2xγ2,ifx<x~.w(x)=\begin{cases}a_{1}x^{2}+b_{1}x+c_{1}+d_{1}x^{\gamma_{1}},&\text{if}\;x\geq\widetilde{x}\\ a_{2}x^{2}+b_{2}x+c_{2}+d_{2}x^{\gamma_{2}},&\text{if}\;x<\widetilde{x}\;.\end{cases} (7.16)

If x(0,+)\forall x\in(0,+\infty) w′′(x)>0w^{\prime\prime}(x)>0 and (i) g′′(u)0g^{\prime\prime}(u)\neq 0 u[U1,U2]\forall u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}], or (ii) gg is given by (2.6), then ww is the value function (i.e. w=vw=v) and u={u(Xtu)}t0u^{*}=\{u^{*}(X^{u^{*}}_{t})\}_{t\geq 0} is an optimal strategy, where the function u(x)u^{*}(x) is given by:

Case (i)

u(x)={U1x{x(0,+)0w(x)(g(U1)+1)}U2x{x(0,+)0w(x)(g(U2)+1)}u^otherwise,u^{*}(x)=\begin{cases}-U_{1}&x\in\Set{x\in(0,+\infty)\mid 0\geq w^{\prime}(x)(g^{\prime}(-U_{1})+1)}\\ U_{2}&x\in\Set{x\in(0,+\infty)\mid 0\leq w^{\prime}(x)(g^{\prime}(U_{2})+1)}\\ \hat{u}&\text{otherwise}\;,\end{cases} (7.17)

where u^\hat{u} is the unique solution to

g(u)=1u[U1,U2].g^{\prime}(u)=-1\quad u\in[-U_{1},U_{2}]\;.

Case (ii)

u(x)={U1x{x(0,+)w(x)(α1)0}U2x{x(0,+)w(x)(α1)<0}.u^{*}(x)=\begin{cases}-U_{1}&x\in\Set{x\in(0,+\infty)\mid w^{\prime}(x)(\alpha-1)\geq 0}\\ U_{2}&x\in\Set{x\in(0,+\infty)\mid w^{\prime}(x)(\alpha-1)<0}\;.\end{cases} (7.18)
Proof.

It is sufficient to show that all the conditions of the Verification Theorem 5.2 are satisfied. First we prove that ww is twice continuous differentiable, by construction we have that w(x~+)=w(x~)w(\widetilde{x}^{+})=w(\widetilde{x}^{-}), w′′(x~+)=w′′(x~)w^{\prime\prime}(\widetilde{x}^{+})=w^{\prime\prime}(\widetilde{x}^{-}) and w(x~+)=0w^{\prime}(\widetilde{x}^{+})=0. Let us observe that w(x~)=w(x~+)=0w^{\prime}(\widetilde{x}^{-})=w^{\prime}(\widetilde{x}^{+})=0 because ww is twice differentiable on (0,+)(0,+\infty). Since ww^{\prime} is strictly increasing, we have that w(x)0w^{\prime}(x)\geq 0 for xx~x\geq\widetilde{x} and w(x)<0w^{\prime}(x)<0 for x<x~x<\widetilde{x}. ww solves the HJB equation (6.2) and satisfies the quadratic growth condition by construction. Then the statement follows by Propositions 6.3, 6.4 and the Verification Theorem 5.2. ∎

Remark 7.1.

Let us observe that (7.18) reads as:

  • for 0<α<10<\alpha<1:

    u(x)={U2ifxx~U1ifx<x~;u^{*}(x)=\begin{cases}U_{2}&\text{if}\,x\geq\widetilde{x}\\ -U_{1}&\text{if}\,x<\widetilde{x}\;;\end{cases} (7.19)
  • for α>1\alpha>1

    u(x)={U1ifxx~U2ifx<x~.u^{*}(x)=\begin{cases}-U_{1}&\text{if}\,x\geq\widetilde{x}\\ U_{2}&\text{if}\,x<\widetilde{x}\;.\end{cases} (7.20)

We can distinguish two cases. When the impact of fiscal policy on GDP growth is low (i.e. 0<α<10<\alpha<1), the government applies the maximum surplus, increasing taxes and decreasing the public spending, as long as the current debt-GDP ratio is over the threshold x~\widetilde{x}. When XtX_{t} is below x~\widetilde{x}, the maximum deficit is applied. This simple rule is reversed when α>1\alpha>1, that is when the fiscal policy is more effective on GDP growth than on debt.

In the sequel we perform some numerical simulations to further investigate the results of Proposition 7.2. In particular, we refer to the case (ii), when the GDP growth rate takes the form of equation (2.6), that is

g(z,u)=g0αu.g(z,u)=g_{0}-\alpha u\;.

We consider the parameters in Table 1 below as a reference scenario, unless otherwise specified.

Table 1: Simulation parameters
Parameter Value
rr 0.010.01
g0g_{0} 0.030.03
σ\sigma 0.20.2
x¯\bar{x} 0.60.6
U1=U2U_{1}=U_{2} 11
α\alpha 0.90.9
λ\lambda 55

The main task is to solve numerically (7.15). Then we can investigate how the result is sensitive to the model parameters.

For instance, given the parameters as in Table 1, we can find a solution to equation (7.15), that is x~=0.6194\tilde{x}=0.6194, so that the value function is well defined and it is illustrated in Figure 1. The reader can easily notice that it is convex, as expected.

Refer to caption
Figure 1: The value function given by equation (7.16).

Recalling (2.11) we get that the uncontrolled debt ratio is given by

Xt0,x=xe(rg012σ2)t+σWt,t0,X^{0,x}_{t}=xe^{(r-g_{0}-\frac{1}{2}\sigma^{2})t+\sigma W_{t}},\quad t\geq 0\;,

hence we call strong economy countries with parameters satisfying g0+σ22>rg_{0}+{\sigma^{2}\over 2}>r and weak economy when the opposite inequality holds, that is g0+σ22<rg_{0}+{\sigma^{2}\over 2}<r (e.g. in [5] the same definition is used).

In Table 2 we perform a comparison between countries with different economy parameters; precisely, we consider the parameters r=0.01,g0=0.03,σ=0.2r=0.01,g_{0}=0.03,\sigma=0.2 corresponding to a strong economy and r=0.07,g0=0.015,σ=0.3r=0.07,g_{0}=0.015,\sigma=0.3 for a weak economy.

Table 2: Comparison between strong and weak economies
Parameters Strong Economy Weak Economy
α=0.9\alpha=0.9 x~=0.6194\tilde{x}=0.6194 x~=0.6241\tilde{x}=0.6241
α=0.95\alpha=0.95 x~=0.6052\tilde{x}=0.6052 x~=0.5941\tilde{x}=0.5941
U1=U2=0.8U_{1}=U_{2}=0.8 x~=0.6125\tilde{x}=0.6125 x~=0.6068\tilde{x}=0.6068
U1=U2=0.5U_{1}=U_{2}=0.5 x~=0.6052\tilde{x}=0.6052 x~=0.5941\tilde{x}=0.5941

First, we noticed that the solution x~\tilde{x} is symmetric with respect to α=1\alpha=1, i.e. x~\tilde{x} for α=0.9\alpha=0.9 and α=0.95\alpha=0.95 is the same as for α=1.1\alpha=1.1 and α=1.05\alpha=1.05, respectively. We can observe that when the effect of fiscal policy on GDP, which is measured by α\alpha, is closer to the effect on debt, which is a unitary, then the threshold x~\tilde{x} decreases. In particular, for the weak economy this phenomenon is more evident and x~\tilde{x} becomes lower than the target debt x¯\bar{x}. Moreover, when the fiscal margin is reduced (U1U_{1} and U2U_{2} go from 11 to 0.80.8 and 0.50.5) we can see that x~\tilde{x} decreases, becoming closer to x¯\bar{x}. Hence, when the fiscal policy is less effective, the government should intervene even when minimal deviations from the target are observed.

To clarify the government behavior and give a deeper insight into Remark 7.1, we simulate a trajectory of debt-GDP ratio with the corresponding optimal strategy.

Figure 2 illustrates a trajectory of the (optimally) controlled Debt-GDP. Recall that in this case 0<α<10<\alpha<1, hence the optimal strategy follows equation (7.19). Let us recall that here we have x~=61.94%\tilde{x}=61.94\%, while our target is x¯=60%\bar{x}=60\%. For instance, let us comment the first two months as illustrated in the picture. Starting from a debt-GDP ratio of 70%70\%, the government applies the maximum surplus U2U_{2} according to the optimal strategy. We observe the debt decreasing and after 51 days the debt hits the threshold x~\tilde{x}, so that the maximum deficit U1-U_{1} is applied. Then the debt increases again and the government will stop spending when the threshold is hit again.

Refer to caption
Figure 2: A simulation of the Debt-GDP ratio (left y axis) with the corresponding optimal strategy (right y axis). Here x~=61.94%\tilde{x}=61.94\% and x¯=0.60%\bar{x}=0.60\%. The solid line represents the controlled process, while the dotted line is the Debt-GDP ratio without intervention.

Conclusions

The present article introduces a new dynamic stochastic model for the debt-GDP ratio, see equation (2.3), trying to fill the gap between the economic theory and the mathematical model formulation. In particular, the expansionary/recessionary role of the fiscal policy on the GDP were not fully recognized by some recent research papers, while this phenomenon is well known in Economics.
We study a general class of debt management problems as a stochastic control problem with a generic functional cost, depending on debt-GDP ratio, an exogenous stochastic factor ZZ and the fiscal policy. In Section 6 we provide a characterization of the value function as a viscosity solution of the HJB equation, see Theorem 5.1. Moreover, a verification theorem (see Theorem 5.2) is proved when a classical solution of the HJB equation exists. Then in Section 6 we investigate the optimal candidate fiscal policy in many cases of interest. Some practical applications have been analyzed in Section 7.

Our results give many interesting insights on the government interventions for managing public debt issues. When the fiscal policy uu has a nonlinear impact on GDP growth, the government will select the primary balance in order that the effect on GDP matches that on debt. When this is not possible, the extreme policies (maximum deficit or maximum surplus) are chosen (see Proposition 6.3). When the effect of uu on GDP is linear, a bang-bang strategy is obtained.
When the cost functional does not depend on uu and it is increasing in xx (e.g. for debt reduction), we proved that the maximum surplus U2U_{2} is applied only when its marginal negative effect on GDP is lower than the positive effect on debt reduction. Similarly, the maximum deficit is optimal when its marginal beneficial effect on GDP surpasses the negative effect of increasing debt (see Proposition 6.5).

In general, it turns out that the impact of the fiscal policy on GDP is crucial to determine the optimal taxation/spending level and the corresponding optimal debt-GDP ratio. In particular, depending on the macroeconomic conditions (described by ZZ) and the magnitude of the impact of the fiscal policy on GDP, the optimal debt management can be achieved by deficit policies in some circumstances. This is still true when the government goal is debt reduction, as shown in Section 7.1.

Declarations

Funding The authors work has been partially supported by the Project INdAM-GNAMPA, number: U-UFMBAZ-2020-000791.
Conflicts of interest/Competing interests The authors declare no conflict of interest.
Availability of data and material Not applicable.
Code availability Not applicable.
Ethics approval Not applicable.
Consent to participate Not applicable.
Consent for publication Not applicable.

References

  • [1] B. Annicchiarico, F. D. Dio, and S. Patrì. Optimal Correction of the Public Debt and Fiscal Resilience Measures. CEIS Research Paper 479, Tor Vergata University, CEIS, Apr. 2020.
  • [2] R. J. Barro. On the determination of the public debt. Journal of Political Economy, 87(5, Part 1):940–971, 1979.
  • [3] O. J. Blanchard. Debt, deficits, and finite horizons. Journal of Political Economy, 93(2):223–247, 1985.
  • [4] A. Cadenillas and R. Huamán-Aguilar. Explicit formula for the optimal government debt ceiling. Annals of Operations Research, 247(2):415–449, Dec 2016.
  • [5] A. Cadenillas and R. Huamán-Aguilar. On the failure to reach the optimal government debt ceiling. Risks, 6(4), 2018.
  • [6] G. Callegaro, C. Ceci, and G. Ferrari. Optimal reduction of public debt under partial observation of the economic growth. Finance and Stochastics, 24(4):1083–1132, October 2020.
  • [7] F. Casalin, E. Dia, and A. H. Hallett. Public debt dynamics with tax revenue constraints. Economic Modelling, 2019.
  • [8] J. B. Delong and L. H. Summers. Fiscal policy in a depressed economy. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:233 – 297, 2012.
  • [9] E. D. Domar. The ”burden of the debt” and the national income. The American Economic Review, 34(4):798–827, 1944.
  • [10] A. Fatás and L. H. Summers. The permanent effects of fiscal consolidations. Journal of International Economics, 112:238 – 250, 2018.
  • [11] G. Ferrari. On the optimal management of public debt: a singular stochastic control problem. SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization, 56(3):2036 – 2073, 2018.
  • [12] G. Ferrari and N. Rodosthenous. Optimal control of debt-to-gdp ratio in an n-state regime switching economy. SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization, 58(2):755 – 786, 2020.
  • [13] B. Fincke and A. Greiner. Do large industrialized economies pursue sustainable debt policies? a comparative study for japan, germany and the united states. Japan and the World Economy, 23(3):202 – 213, 2011.
  • [14] R. Neck and J. E. Sturm. Sustainability of Public Debt. The MIT Press, 2008.
  • [15] J. D. Ostry, A. R. Ghosh, and R. Espinoza. When should public debt be reduced? IMF Staff Discussion Note SDN/15/10, 2015.
  • [16] H. Pham. Continuous-time Stochastic Control and Optimization with Financial Applications. Springer-Verlag, 2009.
  • [17] C. Wyplosz. Fiscal policy: Institutions versus rules. National Institute Economic Review, 191(1):64–78, 2005.