Arbitrage Problems with Reflected Geometric Brownian Motion
Abstract.
Contrary to the claims made by several authors, a financial market model in which the price of a risky security follows a reflected geometric Brownian motion is not arbitrage-free. In fact, such models violate even the weakest no-arbitrage condition considered in the literature. Consequently, they do not admit numéraire portfolios or equivalent risk-neutral probability measures, which makes them totally unsuitable for contingent claim valuation. Unsurprisingly, the published option pricing formulae for such models violate textbook no-arbitrage bounds.
1. Introduction
In a seminal paper, Skorokhod (1961) studied the problem of inserting an instantaneously reflecting boundary into the state space of a one-dimensional Itô diffusion. The resulting process is described by an SDE that contains a new term—called a reflection term—that controls reflection off the boundary, along with the usual drift and diffusion terms. In addition to proving existence and uniqueness results for the solution to this SDE, Skorokhod (1961) derived an explicit expression for the reflection term. Today we recognise the reflection term as the local time of the diffusion at the reflecting boundary.
Several studies have considered financial market models in which the price of a risky security follows a reflected geometric Brownian motion (RGBM). Such a process is obtained by applying Skorokhod’s (1961) construction to a vanilla geometric Brownian motion, causing it to reflect off a lower boundary. For example, Veestraeten (2013), Hertrich (2015), Neuman and Schied (2016) and Hertrich and Zimmermann (2017) have used RGBMs to model exchange rates constrained by central bank target zone policies, while Gerber and Pafumi (2000) and Ko et al. (2010) modelled the value of an investment fund with a capital guarantee as an RGBM. Recently, Thomas (2021) modelled house prices as an RGBM, under the assumption that the government will support the property market if prices fall enough. Related models, where the price of a risky security is constrained by reflecting boundaries but the underlying dynamics is not geometric Brownian motion, have been studied by Feng et al. (2020) and Melnikov and Wan (2021).
Veestraeten (2008) claimed that the RGBM model does not offer any arbitrage opportunities. He justified this claim by noting that the security price follows a continuous process and that the time spent by it on the reflecting boundary has Lebesgue measure zero. Based on those observations, he reasoned that arbitrageurs cannot generate riskless profits by purchasing the security when its price reaches the boundary and selling it when its price is reflected off the boundary. On the strength of this heuristic argument, he concluded that the RGBM model is arbitrage-free and must therefore admit an equivalent risk-neutral probability measure. He then obtained an expression for the density of the putative equivalent risk-neutral probability measure and used it to derive pricing formulae for European puts and calls. Following an amendment to the put pricing formula by Hertrich and Veerstraeten (2013), and with some modifications to cater for dividends, these option pricing formulae have been used by Veestraeten (2013), Hertrich (2015), Hertrich and Zimmermann (2017) and Thomas (2021).
In this paper, we show that Veestraeten’s (2008) argument is unsound and his claim that the RGBM model is arbitrage-free is incorrect. In fact, we demonstrate that the model fails to satisfy even the weakest no-arbitrage condition considered in the literature. Consequently, it does not admit a numéraire portfolio or an equivalent risk-neutral probability measure. These deficiencies make the RGBM model unsuitable for contingent claim valuation and undermine the validity of the option pricing formulae in the articles cited above. In fact, those formulae are shown to behave quite pathologically when the price of the risky security is close to the reflecting boundary.
We begin, in Section 2, with a brief overview of a weak no-arbitrage condition, in the simplified setting of a financial market comprising a bank account and a single non-dividend-paying stock. The primary purpose of this overview is to serve as a roadmap for our subsequent analysis of the RGBM model. In particular, we derive a necessary and sufficient characterisation of the aforementioned no-arbitrage condition that subsequently allows us to pinpoint the exact source of the arbitrage trouble for the RGBM model.
We analyse the RGBM model in Section 3. After setting it up and cataloguing its basic properties, we construct a trading strategy that violates the weak no-arbitrage condition studied in Section 2, and explain how this result is intimately related to the reflecting behaviour of the stock price in the model. The weak no-arbitrage failure of the RGBM model means that it does not admit an equivalent risk-neutral probability measure, invalidating the risk-neutral approach to contingent claim valuation. Consequently, the published option pricing formulae for the model have no theoretical justification. We examine those formulae in detail, demonstrating that they violate textbook no-arbitrage bounds, and we explain those violations in terms of the reflecting behaviour of the stock price.
In summary, this paper makes two significant contributions. First, it establishes that the RGBM model provides an interesting and non-trivial example of a financial market model that violates a weak no-arbitrage condition, and relates this failure to the characteristics of the model.111Our analysis could potentially be extended to other financial market models with reflecting boundaries, such as the models studied by Feng et al. (2020) and Melnikov and Wan (2021). The second contribution is to highlight the erroneous reasoning about the arbitrage properties of the RGBM model in Veestraeten (2008), which has led to the publication of invalid option pricing formulae by Veestraeten (2008, 2013), Hertrich and Veerstraeten (2013), Hertrich (2015), Hertrich and Zimmermann (2017) and Thomas (2021). Of particular concern is Thomas (2021), which recommends the RGBM model to practitioners as a valuation framework for no-negative equity guarantees, a large and important class of insurance products.
2. A Weak No-Arbitrage Condition and Its Consequences
This section develops the theoretical prerequisites for our analysis of the reflected geometric Brownian motion model in Section 3. We begin by introducing a class of continuous financial market models that is general enough to encompass the reflected geometric Brownian motion model as a particular example. In the context of this modelling framework, we then formulate the so-called structure condition, which is expressed in terms of the characteristics of a model, before introducing a weak no-arbitrage condition, known as no increasing profit. Our main result establishes that the structure condition and the no-increasing profit condition are equivalent in our setting. Finally, we summarise the economic and modelling consequences of a failure of the no increasing profit condition.
2.1. A General Modelling Framework
Throughout this paper, we assume the existence of a filtered probability space , whose filtration satisfies the usual conditions of completeness and right-continuity. It is understood that all random variables and stochastic processes are defined on this space and all stochastic processes are adapted to its filtration. Given a continuous semimartingale , we shall write to denote the family of predictable processes , such that the stochastic integral exists.
Consider a financial market comprising a risk-free security and a single risky security. For convenience, we shall refer to the former as a bank account and to the latter as a stock. The value of the bank account is given by , for all , where is a continuously compounding risk-free interest rate. The stock price is determined by the SDE
(2.1) |
for all , with initial value , where is a continuous finite variation process and is a continuous local martingale. For convenience, we shall assume that , for all , which ensures that the stock price is strictly positive, by virtue of the law of large numbers for local martingales (see Revuz and Yor 1999, Exercise V.1.16).
Investors in the market described above are able to trade self-financing portfolios comprising the bank account and the stock. The following definition makes this concept precise.
Definition 2.1.
A trading strategy is a predictable process . Given a trading strategy and an initial endowment , the stochastic process , determined by the SDE
(2.2) |
for all , with initial value , is called the portfolio value generated by and .
Given a trading strategy and an initial endowment , we interpret as the value at time of a self-financing portfolio that holds shares of the stock at each time , with initial value . The SDE (2.2) follows from the self-financing requirement that the portfolio must hold units of the bank account at time , if it holds shares of the stock at that time.
2.2. The Structure Condition
Following Jacod and Shiryaev (2003, Proposition II.2.9), there exists a continuous (and hence predictable) increasing process , such that
(2.3) |
for all , where , and are some predictable processes. One possible choice for is obtained by setting , for all . The next definition formulates the so-called structure condition in terms of the processes , and .
Definition 2.2.
The financial market satisfies the structure condition if there is a predictable process , such that
(2.4) |
for .
The structure condition was first identified by Schweizer (1995), who formulated it somewhat differently. To demonstrate that the two formulations are equivalent, let denote the discounted stock price, defined by , for all . It satisfies the SDE
for all , with , by an application of Itô’s formula. Next, define the continuous finite variation process and the continuous local martingale , by setting
(2.5) |
for all . If the structure condition holds, for some predictable process satisfying (2.4), then
for . On the other hand, if there is a predictable process , such that
(2.6) |
for , then the same reasoning shows that the structure condition holds, with the predictable process satisfying (2.4). So, the structure condition is equivalent to the existence of a predictable process that satisfies (2.6), which is how Schweizer (1995) originally formulated it.
The reformulation of the structure condition above offers a useful insight that will help us interpret the arbitrage properties of the reflected geometric Brownian motion model, studied in Section 3. First, note that the finite variation processes and may be regarded as (possibly signed) random measures on . With that interpretation in mind, (2.6) states that , with predictable density . This means that if then , for and any Borel-measurable set . In particular, if there are measurable subsets of over which the sample paths of increase or decrease but the sample paths of remain constant, then the structure condition cannot hold.
2.3. The No Increasing Profit Condition
An increasing profit is the strongest form of arbitrage for continuous-time financial market models. This concept of arbitrage was introduced by Karatzas and Kardaras (2007) and thoroughly investigated by Fontana (2015). The following definition provides a formulation that is appropriate for our setting.
Definition 2.3.
The financial market admits an increasing profit if there is a trading strategy , such that
-
(1)
is non-decreasing; and
-
(2)
.
The market satisfies the no increasing profit (NIP) condition if no such strategy exists.
Putting the previous definition into words, a model admits an increasing profit if there is a trading strategy, for which the value of the associated portfolio with an initial endowment of zero is a non-decreasing process with a positive probability of ultimately becoming strictly positive. Such arbitrage opportunities are unequivocally pathological, since they offer investors a chance of making something from nothing, without incurring any risk. Equilibrium asset prices cannot exist in a model that offers such opportunities, since there would be insatiable demand for the portfolios that exploit them. Consequently, a viable financial market model must satisfy the NIP condition.
The next theorem reveals that the NIP condition is equivalent to the structure condition. Fontana (2015, Theorem 3.1) proved essentially the same result, but the formulation and proof in our setting are quite different and the proof is sufficiently instructive to merit inclusion. Karatzas and Shreve (1991, Lemma 1.4.6) and Delbaen and Schachermayer (1995, Theorem 3.5) proved related results in the “only iff” direction.
Theorem 2.4.
The NIP condition is satisfied if and only if the structure condition is satisfied.
Proof.
() Suppose the NIP condition holds. Consider a portfolio with initial endowment that implements a trading strategy , specified by
for all . In that case, the quadratic variation of the local martingale satisfies
for all . This implies that , since a local martingale whose quadratic variation is zero must remain constant. Using differential notation, the latter condition can be expressed as , for all . Hence, (2.2) gives
for all . The solution to this equation is
for all . Now consider another trading strategy , with initial endowment , comprising a long position in and a short position in the bank account. The value of the associated portfolio is given by
for all . Since the integrand in this expression is non-negative, it follows that is a non-decreasing process. This implies that , by virtue of the assumption that the NIP condition holds, which is to say that
From this we conclude that , for , whence the predictable process , defined by
for all , satisfies (2.4) and verifies the structure condition.
() Suppose the structure condition is satisfied and let be a trading strategy, for which the value of the associated portfolio with zero initial endowment is non-decreasing. It follows that is a finite variation process, which implies that
for all , whence , for . Since the structure condition holds, by assumption, it follows from (2.4) that , for . Next, observe that also implies that , since a local martingale with zero quadratic variation remains constant. This can be expressed as , for all . Consequently, (2.2) gives
for all . Since we have established that , for , it follows from the expression above that , for all , whence , since . Consequently, , implying that . In summary, we have demonstrated that any trading strategy that satisfies the first condition in Definition 2.3 cannot satisfy the second condition. Hence, the NIP condition holds. ∎
Inspection of (2.4) reveals that the structure condition fails if and only if there are periods during which the process is zero and processes and assume different values. Whenever that happens, the market effectively contains two risk-free securities with different rates of return. During such periods, the trading strategy constructed in the first part of the proof of Thoerem 2.4 generates an increasing profit by borrowing at the lower rate and investing the proceeds at the higher rate. In light of Theorem 2.4, the NIP condition may be interpreted economically as stating that the market never contains two risk-free securities with different rates of return.
2.4. Contingent Claim Valuation
In order for a model to be suitable for contingent claim valuation, it should admit either a numéraire portfolio or an equivalent risk-neutral probability measure. Informally, a numéraire portfolio in our modelling framework is a well-behaved trading strategy , whose portfolio value , with initial endowment , provides a natural benchmark against which the value of every other well-behaved portfolio can be measured. More formally, the benchmarked processes and are required to be supermartingales. On the other hand, an equivalent risk-neutral probability measure in our setting is an equivalent probability measure , such that the discounted stock price is a local martingale under Q. If a model admits a numéraire portfolio, then the benchmark approach to contingent claim valuation (see Platen and Heath 2006) can be used, while traditional risk-neutral valuation can be used if it admits an equivalent risk-neutral probability measure.
Both the existence of well-behaved numéraire portfolio and the existence of an equivalent risk-neutral probability measure can be characterised in terms of no-arbitrage conditions. In more general settings than ours, Karatzas and Kardaras (2007) established that the existence of a well-behaved numéraire portfolio is equivalent to the no unbounded profit with bounded risk (NUPBR) condition, while Delbaen and Schachermayer (1994) famously demonstrated that the no free lunch with vanishing risk (NFLVR) condition is necessary and sufficient for the existence of an equivalent risk-neutral probability measure. Based on those results, a model that does not satisfy NUPBR or NFLVR cannot be used for pricing options and other contingent claims.
Crucially, both NUPBR and NFLVR are stronger conditions that NIP.222The logical dependencies between the various no-arbitrage conditions for continuous financial market models are explained in the surveys by Hulley (2010, Chapter 1) and Fontana (2015). Consequently, a model that does not satisfy the NIP condition will fail to satisfy the NUPBR and NFLVR conditions as well, which means that it will not admit a well-behaved numéraire portfolio or an equivalent risk-neutral probability measure. Such a model is unsuitable for contingent claim valuation. This is unsurprising, since we have already argued that a model cannot sustain equilibrium asset prices if it does not satisfy the NIP condition.
3. A Reflected Geometric Brownian Motion Model
Veestraeten (2008) proposed a modification of the Black and Scholes (1973) model, in which the price of a risky asset is a geometric Brownian with a reflecting lower boundary. A related model was employed by Gerber and Pafumi (2000), and Ko et al. (2010) for the value of an investment fund with a capital guarantee, while Veestraeten (2013), Neuman and Schied (2016), Hertrich (2015), and Hertrich and Zimmermann (2017) used similar models for exchange rates constrained by target zones. Finally, Thomas (2021) recently used reflected geometric Brownian motion to model house prices protected by a government guarantee. This section provides a careful analysis of the arbitrage properties of the reflected geometric Brownian motion model. We begin with a rigorous formulation of the model, before describing its basic properties. Next, we demonstrate that it violates both the no increasing profit condition and the structure condition, before analysing those failures in terms of the reflecting behaviour of the asset price in the model. Finally, we demonstrate that the option pricing formulae for the model, presented in several of the previously cited studies, exhibit numerous pathologies, which are once again related to the reflecting behaviour of the asset price in the model.
3.1. Reflected Geometric Brownian Motion
Skorokhod (1961) showed that the SDE
(3.1) |
for all , with a lower reflecting boundary and initial value , admits a unique strong solution. This solution comprises a pair of processes and , such that
(3.2a) | |||
(3.2b) | |||
(3.2c) | |||
(3.2d) |
for all , and where the integrals above are well-defined. The process is called a reflected geometric Brownian motion (RGBM) and the process is called the reflection term.
Condition (3.2c) ensures that the value of does not change while the value of exceeds , in which case condition (3.2d) ensures that behaves like a vanilla geometric Brownian motion (GBM). However, as soon as reaches the boundary , the value of increases, instantaneously reflecting back into the interval , after which it behaves like a vanilla GBM once again. It follows that the points of increase of are limited to times when visits . It is natural to interpret as the cumulative amount of reflection of from the boundary , up time .
In addition to establishing the existence of a unique solution to (3.1), Skorokhod (1961) showed that the reflection term is given by
for all , where the integral in this expression can be defined rigorously as a limit of integral sums. There is, however, a more useful interpretation of the reflection term. Define the process , by setting
(3.3) |
for all . This process, which is known as the local time of at , provides a non-trivial measure of the amount of time spends in the vicinity of . Pilipenko (2014, Theorem 1.3.1) showed that , for all , which is to say that the reflection term is just the scaled local time at the reflecting boundary.
3.2. Model Specification
We shall now revisit the financial market described in Section 2, comprising a risk-free bank account and a non-dividend-paying stock. As before, the value of the bank account is given by , for all , where is the risk-free interest rate. However, following Veestraeten (2008), we now assume that the stock price follows the RGBM (3.1).
We begin by noting that the RGBM model falls within the scope of the framework introduced in Section 2, which ensures that the analysis in that section is fully applicable to it. Indeed, (3.2c) allows us to rewrite (3.1) as
for all . This equation may in turn be expressed in the form (2.1), with the continuous finite variation process and the continuous local martingale given by
(3.4) |
for all . As noted in Section 2, there exists a continuous increasing process satisfying (2.3), for some predictable processes , and . That is to say,
(3.5) |
for all . Setting , for all , provides a convenient choice for the process .
3.3. Failure of the No Increasing Profit Condition
The behaviour of the stock price at the reflecting boundary raises concerns about the arbitrage properties of the RGBM model. Indeed, it seems plausible that an arbitrageur could exploit this behaviour by purchasing the stock when its price reaches the boundary and unwinding the position immediately afterwards, as the stock price is reflected off the boundary. The guiding intuition is that, upon reaching the boundary, the behaviour of the stock price is completely predictable over the next instant of time, and therefore arbitrageable. The following proposition confirms this intuition.333The trading strategy constructed in the proof of Proposition 3.1 is similar in spirit to the trading strategy in Fontana (2015, Example 7.1).
Proposition 3.1.
The RGBM model violates the NIP condition.
Proof.
Define the process , by setting , for all . Then is predictable, since it is obtained by applying the measurable function to the continuous (and hence predictable) process . Moreover, since every bounded predictable process is integrable with respect to any semimartingale, it follows that , which establishes that is a valid trading strategy. Now, since , for , the properties of the Lebesgue and Itô integrals and the local time process ensure that
and | ||||
for all . By substituting these identities into (2.2), we see that the value of a portfolio that implements the strategy , with zero initial endowment, satisfies the SDE
(3.6) |
for all . First, since is non-decreasing, it follows that is non-decreasing as well. Second, since , for , it follows that , for all , where denotes the first-passage time of to . Since the properties of geometric Brownian motion ensure that , this implies that . Together, these observations confirm that generates an increasing profit. ∎
Figure 3.1 plots a simulated path for the stock price and the corresponding path for the reflection term, together with the path for the stock position in the arbitrage portfolio described in the proof of Proposition 3.1. Figure 3.11(a) illustrates the reflection of the stock price off the boundary, while Figure 3.11(b) illustrates the behaviour of the the reflection term (which is effectively the local time of the stock price at the boundary). Each time the stock price visits the boundary, we see an instantaneous increase in the refection term, which nudges the stock price away from the boundary. Figure 3.11(c) shows that the stock holding in the arbitrage portfolio switches from zero to one in that instant, before immediately switching back to zero as the stock price is instantaneously reflected off the boundary. In effect, the stock is purchased and immediately sold when its price reaches the boundary, realising a profit equal to the increment in the reflection term in that instant. This profit is deposited in the bank account, so that the value of the arbitrage portfolio at any time is the cumulative sum of the instantaneous profits realised up to that time, plus interest.



In the case when the risk-free interest rate is zero, it follows from (3.6) that the value of the arbitrage portfolio is simply the value of the reflection term (or the scaled local time process). In that case, Figure 3.11(b) also illustrates the behaviour of the value of the arbitrage portfolio. We see that the portfolio requires no initial investment of capital, since its initial value is zero. We also see that its value is non-decreasing, which reflects the riskless nature of the strategy as well as the fact that it requires no trading capital to fund margin calls. Moreover, the portfolio value increases instantaneously from zero at the first-passage time of the stock price to the reflecting boundary, and increases again each subsequent time the stock price visits the boundary. Effectively, the arbitrage strategy harvests the local time of the stock price at the boundary as a riskless profit.
Veestraeten (2008) claimed that the RGBM model does not admit arbitrage opportunities. He justified this assertion by citing two properties of the stock price in the model. First, since reflection off the boundary is instantaneous, the Lebesgue measure of the time spent there by the stock price is zero. Second, the stock price follows a continuous process. Based on those two observations (both of which are correct), he argued that the model is arbitrage-free and therefore admits an equivalent risk-neutral probability measure. Although Proposition 3.1 refutes this argument, we shall nevertheless dwell on it, because it has been repeated by several other authors.
The main problem is that Veestraeten’s (2008) argument focuses on the wrong measure of the time spent by the stock price at the reflecting boundary. Although the Lebesgue measure of the time spent there is indeed zero, that is irrelevant. Instead, we should focus on the local time of the stock price at the boundary. Being a continuous process whose paths are of unbounded total variation on compact intervals means that the sample paths of the stock price are extremely irregular. As a result of this irregularity, the stock price spends a non-zero amount of time infinitesimally close to the boundary, each time it visits, even though it spends no time actually on the boundary. The time spent arbitrarily close to the boundary is what the local time process measures. Each time the stock price reaches the boundary, the clock measuring its local time there ticks over and the local time increment is added to the stock price, nudging it away from the boundary. The arbitrage strategy constructed in the proof of Proposition 3.1 exploits this behaviour, by purchasing and immediately selling the stock each time it reaches the boundary, risklessly harvesting the local time increments in the process.
Another problem with Veestraeten’s (2008) argument is its apparent reliance on the idea that it is practically impossible for an arbitrageur to time their trades to coincide with the stock price reaching and leaving the reflecting boundary. Mathematically, an arbitrage is merely predictable process that satisfies certain technical conditions, and a model is arbitrage-free (in the appropriate sense) if no such process exists. The question of whether the strategy could be implemented in practice has no bearing on its existence as a well-defined mathematical object, and is thus irrelevant to the arbitrage properties of the model. Even though no trader could implement the strategy described in the proof of Proposition 3.1, it nevertheless exists as a well-defined predictable process satisfying the conditions in Definition 2.3.
3.4. Failure of the Structure Condition
Theorem 2.4 showed that a continuous financial market model satisfies the NIP condition if and only if it satisfies the structure condition. Proposition 3.1 proved that the RGBM model does not satisfy the NIP condition, by explicitly constructing an immediate profit strategy. Hence, the structure condition must fail as well. The next proposition proves this directly.
Proposition 3.2.
The RGBM model does not satisfy the structure condition.
Proof.
We can approach Proposition 3.2 from a slightly more intuitive angle. Using (3.4), we obtain the following expressions for the continuous finite variation process and the continuous local martingale , defined by (2.5):
for all , where is the discounted stock price. Since the local time of the stock price at the reflecting boundary increases instantaneously each time gets there, while the Lebesgue measure of the time spent by the stock price at the boundary is zero, we have
for . Consequently,
and | ||||
for . Since , it follows that , in violation of the structure condition.444See the interpetation of the structure condition following Definition 2.2. In other words, the structure condition fails because a non-trivial set of paths of (those for which the first-passage time of the stock price to the reflecting boundary is finite) increase on sets of Lebesgue-measure zero (corresponding to the times when the stock price is at the reflecting boundary), while the paths of cannot change on sets of Lebesgue-measure zero.
3.5. Inconsistent Option Pricing Formulae
Proposition 3.1 established that the RGBM model does not satisfy the NIP condition. As a result, the NFLVR condition also fails, which rules out the existence of an equivalent risk-neutral probability measure. Operating under the mistaken belief that risk-neutral valuation is possible for the RGBM model, Veestraeten (2008) derived pricing formulae for European options written on the stock. Subject to an amendment to the pricing formula for European put options by Hertrich and Veerstraeten (2013), these formulae have also been used by Hertrich (2015) and Hertrich and Zimmermann (2017). Since their derivations are predicated on an incorrect assumption, we expect them to exhibit some inconsistencies.
Suppose we make the counterfactual assumption that an equivalent risk-neutral probability measure does in fact exist for the RGBM model. In that case, the discounted stock price process is a Q-local martingale. Given a European contingent claim written on the stock, with maturity and payoff function , we may (by hypothesis) apply a standard risk-neutral valuation approach to obtain its pricing function , as follows:
for all . Here is the expected value operator with respect to the risk-neutral probability measure , under which .
Consider European call and put options on the stock, with a common strike price of and a common maturity date . The pricing functions for these instruments are given by
(3.7) | ||||
and | ||||
(3.8) |
for all . Veestraeten (2008) derived a putative risk-neutral transition density for the stock price, which Veestraeten (2008), Hertrich and Veerstraeten (2013) and Hertrich (2015) used to evaluate (3.7) and (3.8). In so-doing, they obtained the following pricing functions for European calls and puts:555The option pricing formulae are formulated differently (but equivalently) in the cited papers. We have chosen the formulations in Hertrich (2015, Equations (11) and (12)), which produce compact expressions.
(3.9) |
and
(3.10) |
for all , where
Here denotes the cumulative distribution function for a standard normal random variable.
As an immediate consequence of (3.7), we deduce that
(3.11) |
for all , where the second inequality follows because is a supermartingale under Q, by virtue of Fatou’s lemma.666Since is (by assumption) a local martingale under Q, which is bounded from below, an application of Fatou’s lemma reveals that it is also a Q-supermartingale. Consequently, for all . Note that (3.11) is a model-independent upper bound on call prices, whose violation contradicts the assumption that Q is an equivalent risk-neutral probability measure. The next lemma reveals that this bound can be violated if call prices are determined by (3.9).
Proposition 3.3.
Proof.
Suppose the model parameters satisfy , which is to say that . We consider the price of a call option at time and assume that the stock price is located on the boundary at that time. In that case, (3.9) gives the following expression for the call price:
(3.12) |
Now, since
we can choose a small enough strike price and a large enough risk-free interest rate to ensure that
Using those parameter values, (3.12) gives , in violation of (3.11). The continuity of the call pricing function (3.9) with respect to the stock price ensures that the bound will also be violated for stock prices above the reflecting boundary, but sufficiently close to it. ∎
Proposition 3.3 shows that call prices obtained from (3.9) can exceed the upper bound (3.11) when the stock price is close to the reflecting boundary. This is illustrated in Figure 3.2, which also illustrates that Black and Scholes (1973) call prices are consistent with the upper bound. While the prices obtained from the two formulae converge as the stock price increases, we see that the RGBM call pricing formula (3.9) produces inflated prices that are inconsistent with risk-neutral valuation when the stock price approaches the reflecting boundary. This echoes our analysis of the failures of NIP and the structure condition, which revealed that the arbitrage pathologies of the RGBM model are intimately related to its reflecting behaviour.

We turn our attention now to put options. From (3.8), we obtain
(3.13) |
for all , where the second inequality follows because is a supermartingale under Q, as previously noted. In this case, (3.13) imposes a model-independent lower bound on European put prices, whose violation once again contradicts the assumption that Q is an equivalent risk-neutral probability measure. The next lemma reveals that this bound can be violated if put prices are determined by (3.10).
Proposition 3.4.
Proof.
Suppose the model parameters satisfy , which is to say that . We consider the price of a put option at time and assume that the stock price is located on the boundary at that time. In that case, (3.10) gives the following expression for the put price:
(3.14) |
Now, since
we can choose a large enough strike price to ensure that
Combining this with the fact that
allows us to deduce from (3.14) that , in violation of (3.13). The continuity of the put pricing function (3.10) with respect to the stock price ensures that the bound will also be violated for stock prices above the reflecting boundary, but sufficiently close to it. ∎
Proposition 3.4 shows that put prices obtained from (3.9) can violate the lower bound (3.13) when the stock price is close to the reflecting boundary. This is illustrated in Figure 3.3, which also illustrates that Black and Scholes (1973) put prices are consistent with the lower bound. While the prices obtained from the two formulae converge as the stock price increases, we see that the RGBM put pricing formula (3.10) produces diminished prices that are inconsistent with risk-neutral valuation when the stock price approaches the reflecting boundary. In other words, the pathologies of the RGBM model are once again evident near the reflecting boundary.

We conclude by emphasising that any violation of the bounds (3.11) and (3.13) is inconsistent with the assumption that an equivalent risk-neutral probability measure exists. Consequently, Propositions 3.3 and 3.4 imply that either the option pricing formulae (3.9) and (3.10) are incorrect or the assumption that an equivalent risk-neutral probability measure exists is false.
3.6. Problems with No-Negative-Equity Guarantees
An equity release mortgage (ERM) is a loan made to an elderly property-owning borrower that is collateralised by their property.777ERMS are typically known as reverse mortgages outside the U.K. In the U.K., ERMs typically embody a no-negative equity guarantee (NNEG) stipulating that the amount due for repayment is no more than the minimum of the rolled-up loan amount and the property value at the time of repayment, which would be the time of the borrower’s death or their entry into a care home. This obligation to repay the minimum of two future values implies that a NNEG involves a put option issued to the borrower.
NNEG valuation plays a crucial role in the design and management of ERMs, and several valuation approaches have been considered.888See Buckner and Dowd (2020) for a survey of NNEG valuation. Thomas (2021) recently proposed a new approach, built on the assumption that the government will intervene in the residential real estate market if property prices fall by more than a certain proportion, thereby establishing a de facto lower bound for house prices. Based on this idea, he proposed an RGBM model for house prices, where the lower reflecting boundary corresponds to the level at which the government will enter the property market to support prices. By rearranging the pricing formula for a European put on a dividend-paying security in Hertrich (2015), Thomas (2021) obtained the following formula for the price of a NNEG with maturity date and loan principal , written on a house whose current price is :
(3.15) |
for all , where
and | ||||||
As before, is the continuously compounding risk-free interest rate, while is the volatility of the price of the house. The parameter , which is called the deferment rate, is the continuously compounding discount rate that yields the deferment price of the house, when applied to its current price.999The deferment price of a house is the price payable now, for possession at some future date. Hence, the deferment rate may be regarded as a type of convenience yield.
Since (3.15) is a straightforward extension of the European put pricing formula (3.10), in order to accomodate a dividend-paying stock (with the deferment rate playing the role of a dividend yield), it shares the defects of that formula. First, the non-existence of an equivalent risk-neutral probability measure (or even a numéraire portfolio) for the RGBM model means that there is no economic justification for (3.15) as a pricing formula for NNEGs. Second, an easy modification of Proposition 3.4 shows that (3.15) can violate the model-independent lower bound
(3.16) |
for all , when the house price is close to the reflecting boundary.101010The lower bound (3.16) is a direct analogue of (3.13), for the case of a dividend-paying stock. It can be derived in exactly the same way, if one assumes the existence of an equivalent risk-neutral probability measure. As before, any violation of that bound contradicts the existence of an equivalent risk-neutral probability measure. To make matters worse, the next lemma highlights an additional defect of (3.15) that makes it especially ill-suited to NNEG valuation.
Proposition 3.5.
Proof.
Suppose and , in which case . Fix a current time and a house price , and observe that
and | ||||||
for all . From this it follows that
and | ||||||
by virtue of . Consequently, (3.15) gives
(3.17) |
The second term in this expression is negative, since and , which implies that . We may therefore choose large enough, such that
for all , in violation of (3.16). ∎
Proposition 3.5 shows that NNEG prices obtained from (3.15) violate the lower bound (3.16) for sufficiently long-dated contracts, when the risk-free interest rate is zero and the deferment rate is not too large.111111We could generalise the result by proving that long-dated NNEG prices obtained from (3.15) do not obey (3.16) for any parameter regimes with , but the proof would be messier. Since NNEGs are typically long-dated instruments, the upshot is that they are dramatically undervalued by (3.15) in low interest rate environments.
Figure 3.4 illustrates the issue described by Proposition 3.5. For the chosen parameter values, we see that (3.15) produces NNEG prices below the lower bound (3.16), for maturities in excess of 10 years. We also see that the prices obtained from that formula converge asymptotically to the limit (3.17). By contrast, Black (1976) NNEG prices are consistent with the lower bound (3.16), for all maturities.121212The Black (1976) put pricing formula is proposed by advocates of a market-consistent approach to NNEG valuation (see Buckner and Dowd 2020). To appreciate the severity of the undervaluation issue for long-dated contracts, note that the Thomas (2021) price of a 20-year NNEG in Figure 3.4 is only of the value of the lower bound and a mere of the value of the corresponding Black (1976) NNEG price.

4. Conclusions
Intuitively, an arbitrage is a trading strategy that realises a riskless profit without requiring an upfront investment of capital. But in the context of continuous-time finance, it is best to think of an arbitrage simply as a predictable process that satisfies certain technical conditions, with only a tenuous link to feasible real-world trading strategies. Moreover, there are several notions of arbitrage in continuous-time finance, with different implications for the mathematical features of a model. These observations warn us that intuition and heuristic reasoning are an unreliable substitute for mathematical rigour, when analysing the arbitrage properties of a continuous-time financial market model.
The salience of this warning is illustrated by the recent literature advocating the use of reflected geometric Brownian motion (RGBM) as a security price model. Several authors have argued that the RGBM model does not offer any arbitrage opportunities, but their argument is informal and heuristic. In particular, they do not specify what type of arbitrage opportunities are precluded and they do not formally verify the associated no-arbitrage condition. Instead, they appeal to an intuitive idea that arbitrageurs cannot profit from the reflecting behaviour of the security price in the model because the price process is continuous and the time spent on the reflecting boundary has Lebesgue measure zero. Based on these observations, they wrongly conclude that the RGBM model admits an equivalent risk-neutral probability measure, which leads them to derive invalid option pricing formulae.
A careful mathematical analysis of the RGBM model shows that it violates even the weakest no-arbitrage condition considered in the literature. Consequently, it does not offer any of the structural features required for contingent claim valuation. In particular, it does not admit a numéraire portfolio or an equivalent risk-neutral probability measure. As a result, there is no theoretical justification for the published RGBM option pricing formulae. Indeed, a close examination of those formulae reveals that they behave pathologically under certain conditions.
References
- Black (1976) Black, F. (1976). The pricing of commodity contracts. J. Finan. Econ. 3(1–2), 167–179.
- Black and Scholes (1973) Black, F. and M. Scholes (1973). The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. J. Pol. Econ. 81(3), 637–654.
- Buckner and Dowd (2020) Buckner, D. and K. Dowd (2020). The Eumaeus guide to equity release mortgage valuation: Restating the case for a market consistent approach. Technical report, The Eumaeus Project. Second edition.
- Delbaen and Schachermayer (1994) Delbaen, F. and W. Schachermayer (1994). A general version of the fundamental theorem of asset pricing. Math. Ann. 300(3), 463–520.
- Delbaen and Schachermayer (1995) Delbaen, F. and W. Schachermayer (1995). The existence of absolutely continuous local martingale measures. Ann. Appl. Probab. 5(4), 926–945.
- Feng et al. (2020) Feng, L., P. Jiang, and Y. Wang (2020). Constant elasticity of variance models with target zones. Physica A 537, 1–22.
- Fontana (2015) Fontana, C. (2015). Weak and strong no-arbitrage conditions for continuous financial markets. Int. J. Theor. Appl. Finance 18(1), 34.
- Gerber and Pafumi (2000) Gerber, H. U. and G. Pafumi (2000). Pricing dynamic investment fund protection. N. Amer. Actuarial J. 4(2), 28–37.
- Hertrich (2015) Hertrich, M. (2015). A cautionary note on the put-call parity under an asset pricing model with a lower reflecting barrier. Swiss J. Econ. Statist. 151(3), 227–260.
- Hertrich and Veerstraeten (2013) Hertrich, M. and D. Veerstraeten (2013). Valuing stock options when prices are subject to a lower boundary: A correction. J. Futures Markets 33(9), 889–890.
- Hertrich and Zimmermann (2017) Hertrich, M. and H. Zimmermann (2017). On the credibility of the Euro/Swiss Franc floor: A financial market perspective. J. Money, Credit, Banking 49(2–3), 567–578.
- Hulley (2010) Hulley, H. (2010). Strict Local Martingales in Continuous Financial Market Models. Ph. D. thesis, University of Technology, Sydney.
- Jacod and Shiryaev (2003) Jacod, J. and A. N. Shiryaev (2003). Limit Theorems for Stochastic Processes (Second ed.). Berlin: Springer.
- Karatzas and Kardaras (2007) Karatzas, I. and C. Kardaras (2007). The numéraire portfolio in semimartingale financial models. Finance Stoch. 11(4), 447–493.
- Karatzas and Shreve (1991) Karatzas, I. and S. E. Shreve (1991). Brownian Motion and Stochastic Calculus (Second ed.). New York: Springer.
- Ko et al. (2010) Ko, B., E. S. W. Shiu, and L. Wei (2010). Pricing maturity guarantee with dynamic withdrawal benefit. Ins.: Mathematics Econ. 47(2), 216–223.
- Melnikov and Wan (2021) Melnikov, A. and H. Wan (2021). On modifications of the Bachelier model. Ann. Finance 17(2), 187–214.
- Neuman and Schied (2016) Neuman, E. and A. Schied (2016). Optimal portfolio liquidation in target zone models and catalytic superprocesses. Finance Stoch. 20(2), 495–509.
- Pilipenko (2014) Pilipenko, A. (2014). An Introduction to Stochastic Differential Equations with Reflection. Potsdam: Potsdam University Press.
- Platen and Heath (2006) Platen, E. and D. Heath (2006). A Benchmark Approach to Quantitative Finance. Berlin: Springer.
- Revuz and Yor (1999) Revuz, D. and M. Yor (1999). Continuous Martingales and Brownian Motion (Third ed.). Berlin: Springer.
- Schweizer (1995) Schweizer, M. (1995). On the minimal martingale measure and the Föllmer-Schweizer decomposition. Stoch. Anal. Appl. 13(5), 573–599.
- Skorokhod (1961) Skorokhod, A. V. (1961). Stochastic equations for diffusion processes in a bounded region. Theory Probab. Appl. 6(3), 264–274.
- Thomas (2021) Thomas, R. G. (2021). Valuation of no-negative-equity guarantees with a lower reflecting barrier. Ann. Actuar. Sci. 15(1), 115–143.
- Veestraeten (2008) Veestraeten, D. (2008). Valuing stock options when prices are subject to a lower boundary. J. Futures Markets 28(3), 231–247.
- Veestraeten (2013) Veestraeten, D. (2013). Currency option pricing in a credible exchange rate target zone. Appl. Finan. Econ. 23(11), 951–962.