This paper was converted on www.awesomepapers.org from LaTeX by an anonymous user.
Want to know more? Visit the Converter page.

Assessing the practicability of the condition used for dynamic equilibrium in Pasinetti’s theory of distribution.

A. Jayakrishnan Anil Lal S Ielektron Technologies, IIT Madras Research Park, Taramani, Chennai, India - 600 113
Email: a.jayakrishnan.tfmab@gmail.com
College of Engineering,Trivandrum, Kerala, India - 695016.
Email: anillal@cet.ac.in
Abstract

In this note an assessment of the condition Kw/K=Sw/SK_{w}/K=S_{w}/S is made to interpret its meaning to the Passineti’s theory of distribution[1]. This condition leads the theory to enforce the result sw0s_{w}\rightarrow 0 as Pw0P_{w}\rightarrow 0, which is the Pasinetti’s description about behavior of the workers. We find that the Pasinetti’s claim, of long run worker’s propensity to save as not influencing the distribution of income between profits and the wage can not be generalized. This claim is found to be valid only when W>>PwW>>P_{w} or Pw=0P_{w}=0 with W0W\neq 0. In practice, the Pasinetti’s condition imposes a restriction on the actual savings by one of the agents to a lower level compared to its full saving capacity. An implied relationship between the propensities to save by workers and capitalists shows that the Passineti’s condition can be practiced only through a contract for a constant value of R=sw/scR=s_{w}/s_{c}, to be agreed upon between the workers and the capitalists. It is showed that the Passineti’s condition can not be described as a dynamic equilibrium of economic growth. Implementation of this condition (a) may lead to accumulation of unsaved income, (b) reduces growth of capital, (c)is not practicable and (d) is not warranted. We have also presented simple mathematical steps for the derivation of the Pasinetti’s final equation compared to those presented in [1].

keywords:
Propensity to save , Full saving capacity , Actual saving , Worker’s share on profit , Theory of distribution
journal: Journal

1 Introduction

Pasinetti’s theory of distribution[1] has introduced a correction to the logical slip in Kaldor’s theory[2] of not allocating profit on worker’s saving. Passineti argued that whenever a worker saves a part of his income, he must be allowed to own a portion of the total capital. Otherwise the workers do not save at all. The ownership of assets generates a profit share to the workers in the same manner as that of capitalists. The distribution is expressed as

P=Pc+PwP=P_{c}+P_{w} (1)

Where PcP_{c} and PwP_{w} are profit shares to capitalists and workers respectively. This correction leads to workers getting a feel of ownership along with a consequent increase in their total income. Now, the total income of workers becomes Pw+WP_{w}+W, where WW is worker’s wage. The propensities to save by the workers (sws_{w}) and the capitalists (scs_{c}) result in the partial savings of capitalists Sc=scPcS_{c}=s_{c}P_{c} and workers Sw=sw(Pw+W)S_{w}=s_{w}(P_{w}+W) and the total saving SS as

S=Sc+Sw=scPc+sw(Pw+W)S=S_{c}+S_{w}=s_{c}P_{c}+s_{w}(P_{w}+W) (2)

The purpose of this note is to interpret the meaning of the following condition Pasinetti has used for the dynamic equilibrium of economic growth.

SwS=KwK\frac{S_{w}}{S}=\frac{K_{w}}{K} (3)

where KwK_{w}, KcK_{c} and K=Kw+KcK=K_{w}+K_{c} are the quantity of capital owned by workers, capital owned by the capitalists and total capital respectively. The condition in equation(3) is referred to in this note as Pasinetti’s condition for the dynamic equilibrium. Another assumption used in the derivation of the Pasinetti’s final equation for the theory of distribution is a constant profit ratio given by

PwKw=PcKc=PK\frac{P_{w}}{K_{w}}=\frac{P_{c}}{K_{c}}=\frac{P}{K} (4)

Dividing equation(1) through out by KK we can write

PKPwK=PcK\displaystyle\frac{P}{K}-\frac{P_{w}}{K}=\frac{P_{c}}{K}
PKPwKwKwK=PcK\displaystyle\frac{P}{K}-\frac{P_{w}}{K_{w}}\frac{K_{w}}{K}=\frac{P_{c}}{K}
PKPKKwK=PcK(constant profit ratio in equation-4)\displaystyle\frac{P}{K}-\frac{P}{K}\frac{K_{w}}{K}=\frac{P_{c}}{K}~~~(\because\mbox{constant profit ratio in equation-\ref{asump2}})
PK[1KwK]=PcK\displaystyle\frac{P}{K}\left[1-\frac{K_{w}}{K}\right]=\frac{P_{c}}{K} (5)

Now, the Pasinetti’s condition for dynamic equilibrium in equation(3) is applied to simplify the above expression to obtain the following equation.

PK[1SwS]=PcKorPK[ScS]=PcK\displaystyle\frac{P}{K}\left[1-\frac{S_{w}}{S}\right]=\frac{P_{c}}{K}~~~~~\mbox{or}~~~~~~\frac{P}{K}\left[\frac{S_{c}}{S}\right]=\frac{P_{c}}{K} (6)

By taking S=IS=I and Sc=scPcS_{c}=s_{c}P_{c}, we get

PK[scPcI]=PcKPc[PK1scIK]=0\displaystyle\frac{P}{K}\left[\frac{s_{c}P_{c}}{I}\right]=\frac{P_{c}}{K}\implies P_{c}\left[\frac{P}{K}-\frac{1}{s_{c}}\frac{I}{K}\right]=0

In a capitalist economy Pc0P_{c}\neq 0 and hence we write the Pasinetti’s final equation for distribution as

PK=1scIK\frac{P}{K}=\frac{1}{s_{c}}\frac{I}{K} (7)

It may be noted the mathematical steps used for obtaining the above final equation is simple which students of economics can more easily understand and comprehend in comparison to the one given in [1]. Now we will look at the difference between Pasinetti’s model and Kaldor’s model. In Kaldor’s theory Pw=0P_{w}=0, hence by equations(1)&(2), we have

PK=PcK=SswWKsc=1sc(IswW)K\frac{P}{K}=\frac{P_{c}}{K}=\frac{S-s_{w}W}{Ks_{c}}=\frac{1}{s_{c}}\frac{\left(I-s_{w}W\right)}{K} (8)

The Kaldor’s theory of distribution with sws_{w} taken as equal to zero is

PK=1scIK\frac{P}{K}=\frac{1}{s_{c}}\frac{I}{K} (9)

Pasinetti’s theory as shown in equation(7), obtained without making any assumption on the propensities to save by the workers and Kaldor’s theory obtained with sw=0s_{w}=0 as shown in equation(9), both seem to be exactly the same. Pasinetti has given an interpretation to this match between the equations as a long run insignificance of worker’s propensities to save(sw0s_{w}\rightarrow 0). In this manner he claims that, in the long run worker’s propensity to save does not influence the distribution of income between profits and wage. We argue that the comparison with the assumption sw=0s_{w}=0 of Kaldor’s model by Pasinetti to arrive at a conclusion about the long run worker’s propensities to save is not correct. Truly, Pasinetti’s model starts with a single difference from Kaldor’s model, which is in the share of profit to workers(PwP_{w}). In Kaldor’s model Pw=0P_{w}=0, whereas it is greater than zero in Pasinetti’s model. However, difference between the two models widens by a larger extent, due to inclusion of the Pasinetti’s condition for dynamic equilibrium (equation-3). We now demonstrate the differences between Pasinetti’s and Kaldor’s models. For this, an alternate form of the Pasinetti’s final equation is first derived by subtracting the LHS and RHS of equation(6) from P/KP/K as in the following.

PKPK[ScS]=PKPcKPKSwS=PwK\displaystyle\frac{P}{K}-\frac{P}{K}\left[\frac{S_{c}}{S}\right]=\frac{P}{K}-\frac{P_{c}}{K}\implies\frac{P}{K}\frac{S_{w}}{S}=\frac{P_{w}}{K}

Putting Sw=sw(Pw+W)S_{w}=s_{w}(P_{w}+W) and taking S=IS=I, we get for Pw0P_{w}\neq 0

PK=1sw(PwW+Pw)IK\displaystyle\frac{P}{K}=\frac{1}{s_{w}}\left(\frac{P_{w}}{W+P_{w}}\right)\frac{I}{K} (10)

By equating the right hand sides of equations(7) and (10), we get

sc=sw(1+WPw)\displaystyle s_{c}=s_{w}\left(1+\frac{W}{P_{w}}\right) (11)

It shows that the application of the Pasinetti’s condition results in the propensities getting constrained to satisfy equation(11) and therefore the claim on insignificance of sws_{w} does not remain generalized. The above equation can not be achieved naturally, as the propensities depend on the behavior the capitalists and the workers. Practically, the satisfaction of the condition in equation(11) can be realized through a force of contract or agreement between workers and capitalists.

2 Observations on the relationship between propensities to save

Some observations and the meanings of the equation(11) between the propensities to save by workers and capitalists are enumerated in the following.

  1. 1.

    In the limit as Pw0P_{w}\rightarrow 0, the value of sws_{w} should tend to zero, so as to get a finite value for scs_{c} as per equation(11). This enforces with confirmity, the idea that workers do not save at all if no portion of the profit is shared to them. This idea is incorporated in to the Pasinetti model by merely including the term PwP_{w} in equation(2), which does not enforce sw0s_{w}\rightarrow 0 as Pw0P_{w}\rightarrow 0. Here the logical correction by enforcing sw0s_{w}\rightarrow 0 as Pw0P_{w}\rightarrow 0 is resulted from the uses of the Passineti’s condition and the constant profit ratio.

  2. 2.

    Pasinetti’s model is silent about the spending of WCwW-C_{w} when Pw=0P_{w}=0, where CwC_{w} is the worker’s aggregate consumption.

  3. 3.

    For fixed values of scs_{c} and PwP_{w}, an increase of worker’s wage leads to a reduction of sws_{w}. This is an inconsistency. Here, an increase of worker’s income due to rise of worker’s wages results in a lesser savings.

  4. 4.

    The equations(7) and (9) are same only in terms the variables scs_{c} and II. But the other external variables involved in the two models occur with different ranges/proportions. Hence the interpretation made by Pasinetti on the external variable sws_{w} as a consequence of the same form in equations(7) and (9) can not be generalized.

  5. 5.

    The value of sws_{w} as not influencing the distribution of income between profits and the wage is operational only in conditions such as Pw=0P_{w}=0 when W0W\neq 0 or W>>PwW>>P_{w}.

The above observations related to interpreting the Pasinetti’s final equation and relationship between propensities motivated to look into the insight of this condition for the dynamic equilibrium used by Pasinetti.

3 An insight into Pasinetti’s condition

In the section we obtain a proof to show that the Pasinetti’s condition can not represent a dynamic equilibrium. In the dynamic equilibrium of growth, savings translated into investments in each period is equal to the rate of capital growth in that period. Mathematically,

Sw=dKwdt;Sc=dKcdtandS=dKdt\displaystyle S_{w}=\frac{dK_{w}}{dt};~~~S_{c}=\frac{dK_{c}}{dt}~~~\mbox{and}~~~S=\frac{dK}{dt} (12)

Therefore

Kw(t)=0tSw𝑑t;Kc(t)=0tSc𝑑tandK(t)=0tS𝑑t\displaystyle K_{w}(t)=\int_{0}^{t}S_{w}dt;~~~~~K_{c}(t)=\int_{0}^{t}S_{c}dt~~~\mbox{and}~~~K(t)=\int_{0}^{t}Sdt (13)

And

KwK=0tSw𝑑t0tS𝑑t\displaystyle\frac{K_{w}}{K}=\frac{\int_{0}^{t}S_{w}dt}{\int_{0}^{t}Sdt} (14)

As per the Pasinetti condition in equation(3), this ratio is equal to Sw/SS_{w}/S. This is possible only if the instantaneous savings Sw(t)S_{w}(t) and S(t)S(t) satisfy the conditions

Sw(t)\displaystyle S_{w}(t) =\displaystyle= Cf(t)\displaystyle Cf(t) (15)
Sc(t)\displaystyle S_{c}(t) =\displaystyle= Df(t)\displaystyle Df(t) (16)
S(t)\displaystyle S(t) =\displaystyle= Sw+Sc=Ef(t)\displaystyle S_{w}+S_{c}=Ef(t)

where E=C+DE=C+D. Clearly, at any point in time the ratio of propensities is Sw/Sc=C/D=RS_{w}/S_{c}=C/D=R. This ratio rule has to be strictly followed at all the time periods without deviating. For keeping a constant value for RR, the actual amount saved by an agent(worker or capitalist) should be different from the amounts that an agent is willing to save based on his Full Capacity to Save(FCS). Let FCSw(t)FCS_{w}(t) and FCSc(t)FCS_{c}(t) be the Full Capacity to Save by the workers and capitalists respectively. In order to write a mathematical form for the actual savings by workers and capitalists for obtaining a constant contract ratio R=Sw/ScR=S_{w}/S_{c} corresponding to a certain capacity ratio R1=FCSw(t)/FCSc(t)R_{1}=FCS_{w}(t)/FCS_{c}(t), we define two conditional functions

M1=max(R1R,0)\displaystyle M_{1}=\max(R_{1}-R,0)
M2=max(RR1,0)\displaystyle M_{2}=\max(R-R_{1},0)

Now the actual savings by workers and capitalists restricted using RR can be written as

Sw(t)\displaystyle S_{w}(t) =\displaystyle= Sw(FCSw(t),FCSc(t),R)=FCSw(t)FCSc(t)M1\displaystyle S_{w}(FCS_{w}(t),FCS_{c}(t),R)=FCS_{w}(t)-FCS_{c}(t)M_{1} (17)
Sc(t)\displaystyle S_{c}(t) =\displaystyle= Sc(FCSw(t),FCSc(t),R)=FCSw(t)M2+R1\displaystyle S_{c}(FCS_{w}(t),FCS_{c}(t),R)=\frac{FCS_{w}(t)}{M_{2}+R_{1}} (18)

The selection of savings in the above manner leads to lesser saving by one of the agents, who has a higher capacity/willingness to save. The agent who has a higher capacity to save is forced to save less during the process of negotiating a constant value for RR. The unsaved capacity to save by workers and capitalists, denoted as USw(t)US_{w}(t) and USc(t)US_{c}(t) are given by

USw(t)\displaystyle US_{w}(t) =\displaystyle= FCSc(t)M1\displaystyle FCS_{c}(t)M_{1} (19)
USc(t)\displaystyle US_{c}(t) =\displaystyle= FCSc(t)M2M2+R1\displaystyle\frac{FCS_{c}(t)M_{2}}{M_{2}+R_{1}} (20)

The value of US(t)=USw(t)+USc(t)US(t)=US_{w}(t)+US_{c}(t) is either greater than or equal to zero and it becomes equal to zero only when both M1M_{1} and M2M_{2} are equal to zero. Thus, US(t)>0US(t)>0 is common, US(t)=0US(t)=0 is only rarely possible and US(t)=0tUS(t)=0~\forall t is almost impossible. The consequences of US(t)>0US(t)>0 are (a) reduction in the growth of capital due to lesser total investments in all the time periods, (b) reduction in total profit PP and (c) reduction in profit share for one of the agents. Another important drawback arises is from the fact that, the unsaved capacity of an agent in a period will become a component in the Full Capacity to Save of that agent in the next period. This higher capacity to save due to the accumulated unsaved amounts from the previous periods may be further restricted from saving in the subsequent periods as per equations(17) and (18). This may be a matter of a continuous divergence of interests of the agents, rather than attainment of a dynamic equilibrium. In this way the Pasinetti’s condition for dynamic equilibrium as given by equation(3) is not correct. We consider that the contract between the workers and capitalists to practically implement the Pasinetti’s condition encompasses losses from different factors. Again, using the condition of contract, we can derive the following

SwSc=CD=PwPc\displaystyle\frac{S_{w}}{S_{c}}=\frac{C}{D}=\frac{P_{w}}{P_{c}}
sw(W+Pw)scPc=PwPc\displaystyle\frac{s_{w}(W+P_{w})}{s_{c}P_{c}}=\frac{P_{w}}{P_{c}}

For Pc0P_{c}\neq 0, the above equation implies

sc=sw(W+PwPw)\displaystyle s_{c}=s_{w}\left(\frac{W+P_{w}}{P_{w}}\right) (21)

From the equations(11) and (21), it is clear that the relationship between the propensities is resulted from a contract for a constant value of RR to be agreed upon between the workers and the capitalists.

4 Conclusions

An assessment of the practicability of the Pasinetti’s condition (Kw/K=Sw/S)(K_{w}/K=S_{w}/S) used for the dynamic equilibrium of economic growth in his theory of distribution is carried out and the following conclusions have been made.

  1. 1.

    Pasinetti’s condition leads to enforcement of the worker’s behavior given by sw0s_{w}\rightarrow 0 when Pw0P_{w}\rightarrow 0.

  2. 2.

    The Pasinetti model deviates to a larger extent from Kaldor’s model due to the inclusion of the Pasinetti’s condition. Hence the claim by Pasinetti on the long run worker’s propensity to save as not influencing the distribution of income between profits can not be generalized. His claim is found to be valid only when W>>PwW>>P_{w} or Pw=0P_{w}=0 with W0W\neq 0.

  3. 3.

    Pasinetti’s condition implies a relationship between the propensities to save by workers and the capitalists. The relationship between the propensities can not be achieved naturally and requires the force of a contract for a constant value of RR to be agreed upon between the workers and the capitalists.

  4. 4.

    The implementation of Pasinetti’s condition is found to restrict the actual savings by one of the agents to lower levels compared to its full capacity for saving.

  5. 5.

    This condition leads to a reduction of total savings and hence reduces the growth of capital. The amount of unsaved income tend to increase with time. So the Pasinetti’s condition can not be described as a dynamic equilibrium of economic growth.

  6. 6.

    It is concluded that the Pasinetti’s condition is not practicable and hence not warranted for describing the dynamics of growth of economies.

References

  • [1] L. L. Pasinetti, Rate of profit and income distribution in relation to the rate of economic growth, The Review of Economic Studies 29 (4) (1962) 267–279.
  • [2] N. Kaldor, Alternative theories of distribution, The review of economic studies 23 (2) (1955) 83–100.

Appendix A: Illustrative examples on the calculation of actual savings using equations(17) and (18)

Example-1: Given R=15R=\frac{1}{5}, FCSw=5FCS_{w}=5 and FCSc=20FCS_{c}=20.
Now, R1=520=14R_{1}=\frac{5}{20}=\frac{1}{4}, M1=max(R1R,0)=max(120,0)=120M_{1}=\max(R_{1}-R,0)=\max\left(\frac{1}{20},0\right)=\frac{1}{20}
and M2=max(RR1,0)=max(120,0)=0M_{2}=\max(R-R_{1},0)=\max\left(-\frac{1}{20},0\right)=0
and we have by equations(17) and (18)

Sw(t)\displaystyle S_{w}(t) =\displaystyle= FCSw(t)FCSc(t)M1=520×120=4\displaystyle FCS_{w}(t)-FCS_{c}(t)M_{1}=5-20\times\frac{1}{20}=4
Sc(t)\displaystyle S_{c}(t) =\displaystyle= FCSw(t)M2+R1=50+14=20\displaystyle\frac{FCS_{w}(t)}{M_{2}+R_{1}}=\frac{5}{0+\frac{1}{4}}=20

In this case the workers will save only 44 units which is less than their full capacity by keeping R=420=15R=\frac{4}{20}=\frac{1}{5} as the required value.
   
Example-2: Given R=14R=\frac{1}{4}, FCSw=4FCS_{w}=4 and FCSc=20FCS_{c}=20.
Now, R1=420=15R_{1}=\frac{4}{20}=\frac{1}{5}, M1=max(R1R,0)=max(120,0)=0M_{1}=\max(R_{1}-R,0)=\max\left(-\frac{1}{20},0\right)=0
and M2=max(RR1,0)=max(120,0)=120M_{2}=\max(R-R_{1},0)=\max\left(\frac{1}{20},0\right)=\frac{1}{20}
and we have by equations(17) and (18)

Sw(t)\displaystyle S_{w}(t) =\displaystyle= FCSw(t)FCSc(t)M1=420×0=4\displaystyle FCS_{w}(t)-FCS_{c}(t)M_{1}=4-20\times 0=4
Sc(t)\displaystyle S_{c}(t) =\displaystyle= FCSw(t)M2+R1=4120+15=16\displaystyle\frac{FCS_{w}(t)}{M_{2}+R_{1}}=\frac{4}{\frac{1}{20}+\frac{1}{5}}=16

In this case the capitalists will save only 1616 units which is less than their full capacity by keeping R=416=14R=\frac{4}{16}=\frac{1}{4} as the required value.