11email: zq1012@stu.ouc.edu.cn, 11email: liuwj@ouc.edu.cn, 11email: qfang@ouc.edu.cn, 11email: qqnong@ouc.edu.cn
Constrained Heterogeneous Two-facility Location Games with Max-variant Cost
Abstract
In this paper, we propose a constrained heterogeneous facility location model where a set of alternative locations are feasible for building facilities and the number of facilities built at each location is limited. Supposing that a set of agents on the real line can strategically report their locations and each agent’s cost is her distance to the further facility that she is interested in, we study deterministic mechanism design without money for constrained heterogeneous two-facility location games.
Depending on whether agents have optional preference, the problem is considered in two settings: the compulsory setting and the optional setting. In the compulsory setting where each agent is served by the two heterogeneous facilities, we provide a 3-approximate deterministic group strategyproof mechanism for the sum/maximum cost objective respectively, which is also the best deterministic strategyproof mechanism under the corresponding social objective. In the optional setting where each agent can be interested in one of the two facilities or both, we propose a deterministic group strategyproof mechanism with approximation ratio of at most for the sum cost objective and a deterministic group strategyproof mechanism with approximation ratio of at most 9 for the maximum cost objective.
Keywords:
Mechanism design Facility location Strategyproof Constrained1 Introduction
In the origin mechanism design problem for heterogeneous facility location games, there are a set of strategic agents who are required to report their private information and a social planner intends to locate several heterogeneous facilities by a mechanism based on the reported information, with the purpose of optimizing some social objective. In this paper, we study the problem of locating two heterogeneous facilities under a constrained setting, which means a set of alternative locations are feasible for building facilities and the number of facilities built at each location is limited.
Compared with the origin setting where facilities can be built anywhere in a specific metric space and there is no limit on the number of facilities at each location, our constrained setting models well many practical applications. For example, in the realistic urban planning, facilities can only be built at designated sites and the number of facilities at each site is limited. To accommodate these constraints, we propose a multiset of feasible locations and at most one facility is permitted to build at each location. Further, we focus on the Max-variant where the cost of each agent depends on her distance to the farthest one if she is served by two or more heterogeneous facilities. The Max-variant can be found applications in natural scenarios [26]. For example, a local authority plans to locate different raw material warehouses for several processing plants. Assuming each plant has multiple transport trucks having the same speed, the time that the plant has to wait depends on its distance to the farthest one if it requires raw materials from different sites.
We discuss the mechanism design problem for constrained heterogeneous two-facility location games with Max-variant cost in two settings: the first is the compulsory setting, where each agent is served by the two heterogeneous facilities; the second is the optional setting, where each agent is served by either one of the two facilities or both. Considering that agents may manipulate the facility locations by misreporting their private information, we concentrate on mechanisms that can perform well under some social objective (e.g., minimizing the sum/maximum cost) while guaranteeing truthful report from agents (i.e., strategyproof or group strategyproof).
1.1 Our Contribution
This paper studies deterministic mechanism design without money for constrained heterogeneous two-facility location games with Max-variant cost under the objective of minimizing the sum/maximum cost.
Our key innovations and results are summarized as follows.
In Section 2, we formulate the constrained heterogeneous facility location game with Max-variant cost. We propose a finite multiset of alternative locations which are feasible for building facilities and require that at most one facility can be built at each location. Thus, by adjusting the number of same elements in the multiset, the model can accommodate different scenarios where the number of facilities at the same location is limited.
In Section 3, we focus on deterministic mechanism design in the compulsory setting. We propose a set of adjacent alternative location pairs, which all agents have single peaked preferences over and the optimal solution under the sum/maximum cost objective can always be found in. We prove that any deterministic strategyproof mechanism has an approximation ratio of at least 3 under the sum/maximum cost objective. In addition, we present 3-approximate deterministic group strategyproof mechanisms for both social objectives, which implies that the best deterministic strategyproof mechanisms have been obtained.
In Section 4, we discuss the optional setting. For the sum cost objective, we propose a deterministic group strategyproof mechanism with approximation ratio of at most . For the maximum cost objective, we design a deterministic group strategyproof mechanism with approximation ratio of at most 9.
1.2 Related Work
Mechanism design without money for facility location games has been extensively studied in recent years. Early studies focused on the characterization of strategyproof mechanisms. Moulin [19] identified all the possible strategyproof mechanisms for one-facility location on the line with single peaked preferences, whose results were extended by Schummer & Vohra [21] and Dokow et al. [9] to tree and cycle networks.
Approximate mechanism design without money was initiated by Procaccia & Tennenholtz [20], who studied deterministic and randomized strategyproof mechanisms with constant approximation ratio for facility location games under the sum cost and the maximum cost in three settings: one-facility, two-facility and multiple facilities per agent. Following this research agenda, numerous studies have emerged, including improvements on the lower/upper bound of approximation [17, 14] and further variants.
Cheng et al. [7] introduced approximate mechanism design for obnoxious facility location games where the facility is not desirable to each agent. Zou & Li [29] studied the dual preference setting where the facility can be desirable or undesirable for different agents. Zhang & Li [27] introduced weights to agents and Filos-Ratsikas et al. [12] studied one-facility location problem with double-peaked preferences. Serafino & Ventre [22] introduced heterogeneous two-facility location games where each agent cares about either one facility or both and her cost depends on the sum of distances to her interested facilities (referred to as the Sum-variant). Later, Yuan et al. [26] considered the Min-variant and Max-variant instead and Anastasiadis & Deligkas [1] studied heterogeneous -facility setting with Min-variant. Besides, various individual and social objectives were also studied. Mei et al. [18] introduced a happiness factor to measure each agent’s individual utility. Feigenbaum & Sethuraman [10] considered the -form of the vector of agent-costs instead of the classic sum cost. Cai et al. [4] and Chen et al. [5] studied facility location problems under the objective of minimizing the maximum envy. Ding et al. [8] and Liu et al. [16] considered the envy ratio objective. Zhou et al. [28] studied group-fair facility location problems.
Further, motivated by real-world applications, researchers have begun to study the mechanism design problem with constraints on the facilities. Aziz et al. [2, 3] studied facility location problems with capacity constraints. Chen et al. [6] studied the two-opposite-facility location problem with maximum distance constraint by imposing a penalty. Xu et al. [25] studied minimum distance requirement for the heterogeneous two-facility location problem. In addition, considering that in reality the feasible locations that facilities could be built at are usually limited, mechanism design for facility location games with limited locations were also studied. Sui & Boutilier [23] studied approximately strategyproof mechanisms for facility location games with constraints on the feasible placement of facilities. Feldman et al. [11] studied the one-facility location setting under the sum cost objective in the context of voting embedded in some underlying metric space. Tang et al. [24] further considered the maximum cost objective and the two-facility setting. Li et al. [15] studied the heterogeneous two-facility setting with optional preference, which is also the most related to our work among all studies on the constrained heterogeneous facility location problem. However, there are at least three differences between us: (1) our model requires a limit on the number of facilities at each feasible location and [15] does not; (2) each agent’s location is private and her preference on facilities is public in our model while it is the opposite in [15]; (3) we consider the Max-variant cost while [15] considers the Min-variant where the cost of each agent depends on her distance to the closest facility within her acceptable set.
2 Model
Let be a set of agents located on the real line and be the set of two heterogeneous facilities to be built. Each agent has a location and a facility preference , where is ’s private information and is public. Denote and as the agents’ location profile and facility preference profile, respectively. For , let be the location profile without agent , then . For , denote , , and , then .
Let be a multiset of alternative locations which are feasible for building facilities and at most one facility can be built at each location. Assume without loss of generality that . Denote an instance of the agents by or simply by without confusion.
Individual and Social Objectives. When locating at respectively, denote the facility location profile by . Under Max-variant, the cost of agent is denoted by . While each agent seeks to minimize her individual cost, the social planner aims to minimize the sum cost or maximum cost of the agents. For a location and facility preference profile , the sum cost and the maximum cost under are denoted by and , respectively. Let and be the optimal solution under the sum cost and the maximum cost, respectively.
Considering the limit on facility locations, the mechanism in our constrained setting is defined as follows.
Definition 1
A deterministic mechanism is a function that maps the agents’ location profile and facility preference profile to a location profile of the two facilities, i.e., , where should satisfy and .
Given a mechanism and a reported location profile , the cost of agent under is . The sum cost and maximum cost of are and , respectively. Since agents may misreport their locations to benefit themselves, strategyproofness of mechanisms becomes necessary.
Definition 2
A mechanism is strategyproof if each agent can never benefit from misreporting her location, regardless of the others’ strategies, i.e., for every location and facility preference profile , every agent , and every , .
Definition 3
A mechanism is group strategyproof if for any group of agents misreporting their locations, at least one of them cannot benefit regardless of the others’ strategies, i.e., for every location and facility preference profile , every group of agents and every , there exists such that .
We aim at deterministic strategyproof or group strategyproof mechanisms that can perform well under the sum/maximum cost objective. The worst-case approximation ratio is used to evaluate a mechanism’s performance. Without confusion, denote , , and by , , and respectively for simplicity. The approximation ratio under the sum cost objective is defined as follows and it is similar under the maximum cost objective.
Definition 4
A mechanism is said to have an approximation ratio of under the sum cost objective, if
(1) |
In this paper, we are interested in deterministic strategyproof or group strategyproof mechanisms with small approximation ratio under the sum/maximum cost objective.
Notations. For a location profile , denote the median location in by , the leftmost location in by , the rightmost location by , and the center location by . For a facility preference profile , denote for , and .
3 Compulsory Setting
In this section, we study the compulsory setting where each agent is served by the two heterogeneous facilities, i.e., . For simplicity, we omit or in this section. For example, replace by and the cost of agent under the facility location profile is denoted by .
For the multiset of alternative locations with , denote . Then the real line can be partitioned into zones where the th zone (denoted by ) represents the set of points whose favorite location pair in is . We refer to as the zone of location pair . Obviously, it holds that
(2) |
The preferences of all agents over are (not strictly) single peaked: for each agent with location , her peak (or favorite) in is and her cost under monotonically increases as increases. Based on the single peaked preference, locating at the peak of ’s any th statistic order (denoted by ) is group strategyproof.
Lemma 1
Given a location profile , locating at the peak of in for any is group strategyproof.
Lemma 1 provides a class of group strategyproof mechanisms for the compulsory setting where all agents are served by two facilities. Next we will select proper mechanisms from this class for the sum/maximum cost objective respectively.
3.1 Sum Cost
For the sum cost objective, we first show that there exists an optimal solution where the two facilities are located at adjacent alternatives.
Lemma 2
Given a location profile , there exists an optimal solution in under the sum cost objective.
Intuitively, each agent always prefers the two facilities located as close as possible, since her cost depends on her distance to the farther one. By Lemma 2, an optimal solution (or mechanism) can always be found in steps. However, it may be not strategyproof. Consider an instance with where is sufficiently small. It holds that . Replacing by , we have . Thus, agent 1 with can strictly decrease her cost by reporting .
Theorem 3.1
Under the sum cost objective, any deterministic strategyproof mechanism has an approximation ratio of at least 3.
Mechanism 1. Given a location profile , output the peak of in , i.e., the location pair , breaking ties in any deterministic way.
Theorem 3.2
Mechanism 1 is group strategyproof and has an approximation ratio of 3 under the sum cost objective.
3.2 Maximum Cost
Compared with the sum cost objective, there is a more precise statement on the optimal solution under the maximum cost objective.
Lemma 3
Given a location profile , the peak of in is exactly an optimal solution under the maximum cost objective.
However, the optimal mechanism is not strategyproof. Consider an instance with and . It holds that and for sufficiently small . Replacing by , we have . Thus, agent 2 with can strictly decrease her cost by misreporting .
Theorem 3.3
Under the maximum cost objective, any deterministic strategyproof mechanism has an approximation ratio of at least 3.
Mechanism 2. Given a location profile , output the peak of in , i.e., the location pair , breaking ties in any deterministic way.
Theorem 3.4
Mechanism 2 is group strategy-proof and has an approximation ratio of 3 under the maximum cost objective.
4 Optional Setting
In this section, we discuss the optional setting where each agent can be interested in either one of the two heterogeneous facilities or both. The cost of agent is .
Note that even in the optional setting, each agent has some kind of single peaked preference: if or , she has single peaked preference over ; if , she has single peaked preference over . Our mechanisms will be proposed based on the single peaked preference.
In the following subsections, two mechanisms for one-facility location games will be used as subroutines in our mechanisms. Supposing that a set of agents have single peaked preference over the set of alternative locations , the related results are listed as follows.
SC-Mechanism [11]. Given and , output , breaking ties in any deterministic way.
Proposition 1 ([11])
SC-Mechanism is group strategyproof and has an approximation ratio of 3 under the sum cost objective.
MC-Mechanism [24]. Given and , output , breaking ties in any deterministic way.
Proposition 2 ([24])
MC-Mechanism is group strategyproof and has an approximation ratio of 3 under the maximum cost objective.
4.1 Sum Cost
Mechanism 3. Given a location and facility preference profile , output the facility location profile as follows:
-
if , select , breaking ties in any deterministic way;
-
if and , select , and (if ), breaking ties in any deterministic way;
-
if and , select , and (if ), breaking ties in any deterministic way.
Theorem 4.1
Mechanism 3 is group strategyproof and has an approximation ratio of at most under the sum cost objective.
4.2 Maximum Cost
Mechanism 4. Given a location and facility preference profile , output the facility location profile as follows:
-
if , select , breaking ties in any deterministic way;
-
if , select (if ), and (if ), breaking ties in any deterministic way.
Theorem 4.2
Mechanism 4 is group strategyproof and has an approximation ratio of at most 9 under the maximum cost objective.
5 Conclusion
In this paper, we considered the mechanism design problem for constrained heterogeneous two-facility location games where a set of alternatives are feasible for building facilities and the number of facilities built at each alternative is limited. We studied deterministic mechanisms design without money under the Max-variant cost where the cost of each agent depends on the distance to the further facility. In the compulsory setting where each agent is served by two facilities, we showed that the optimal solution under the sum/maximum cost objective is not strategyproof and proposed a 3-approximate deterministic group strategyproof mechanism which is also the best deterministic strategyproof mechanism for the corresponding social objective. In the optional setting where each agent can be interested in either one of the two facilities or both, we designed a deterministic group strategyproof mechanism with approximation ratio with at most for the sum cost objective and a deterministic group strategyproof mechanism with approximation ratio with at most 9 for the maximum cost objective.
There are several directions for future research. First, the bounds for approximation ratio of deterministic strategyproof mechanisms in the optional setting do not match yet. Are there more desirable bounds in this setting? Second, randomized mechanism design for constrained heterogeneous facility location games remains an open question. Third, the cost of each agent served by two facilities here is simply the sum of her distances from facilities. How about mechanism design for constrained facility location games in more general settings, such as agents having weighted preference for facilities [13]? Further, our model can be extended to include more than two facilities or in more general metric spaces.
5.0.1 Acknowledgements.
This research was supported in part by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (12171444, 11971447, 11871442), the Natural Science Foundation of Shandong Province of China (ZR2019MA052).
References
- [1] Anastasiadis, E., Deligkas, A.: Heterogeneous facility location games. In Proceedings of the 17th international conference on autonomous agents and multiagent systems, 623–631 (2018)
- [2] Aziz, H., Chan, H., Lee, B., Li, B., Walsh, T.: Facility location problem with capacity constraints: Algorithmic and mechanism design perspectives. In Proceedings of the 34th AAAI conference on artificial intelligence 34(2), 1806–1813 (2020). \doi10.1609/aaai.v34i02.5547
- [3] Aziz, H., Chan, H., Lee, B., Parkes, D. C.: The capacity constrained facility location problem. Games and Economic Behavior 124, 478–490 (2020). \doi10.1016/j.geb.2020.09.001
- [4] Cai, Q., Filos-Ratsikas, A., Tang, P.: Facility location with minimax envy. In Proceedings of the 25th international joint conference on artificial intelligence, 137–143 (2016)
- [5] Chen, X., Fang, Q., Liu, W., Ding, Y., Nong, Q.: Strategyproof Mechanisms for 2-Facility Location Games with Minimax Envy. Journal of Combinatorial Optimization, 1–17 (2021). \doi10.1007/978-3-030-57602-8_24
- [6] Chen, X., Hu, X., Tang, Z., Wang, C.: Tight efficiency lower bounds for strategy-proof mechanisms in two-opposite-facility location game. Information Processing Letters 168, 106098 (2021). \doi10.1016/j.ipl.2021.106098
- [7] Cheng, Y., Yu, W., Zhang, G.: Strategy-proof approximation mechanisms for an obnoxious facility game on networks. Theoretical Computer Science 497, 154–163 (2013). \doi10.1016/j.tcs.2011.11.041
- [8] Ding, Y., Liu, W., Chen, X., Fang, Q., Nong, Q.: Facility location game with envy ratio. Computers & Industrial Engineering 148(3), 106710 (2020). \doi10.1016/j.cie.2020.106710
- [9] Dokow, E., Feldman, M., Meir, R., Nehama, I.: Mechanism design on discrete lines and cycles. In Proceedings of the 13rd ACM conference on electronic commerce, 423–440 (2012). \doi10.1145/2229012.2229045
- [10] Feigenbaum, I., Sethuraman, J., Ye, C.: Approximately optimal mechanisms for strategyproof facility location: Minimizing norm of costs. Computer Science and Game Theory 42(2), 277–575 (2017). \doi10.1287/moor.2016.0810
- [11] Feldman, M., Fiat, A., Golomb, I.: On voting and facility location. In Proceedings of the 2016 ACM Conference on Economics and Computation, 269–286 (2016). \doi10.1145/2940716.2940725
- [12] Filos-Ratsikas, A., Li, M., Zhang, J., Zhang, Q.: Facility location with double-peaked preferences. Autonomous Agents and Multi-Agent Systems 31, 1209–1235 (2017)
- [13] Fong, K., Li, M., Lu, P., Todo, T., Yokoo, T.: Facility lcation games with fractional preferences. In Proceedings of the 32nd AAAI Conference on Artificial Intelligence, 1039–1046 (2018). \doi10.1609/aaai.v32i1.11458
- [14] Fotakis, D., Tzamos, C.: On the power of deterministic mechanisms for facility location games. ACM Transactions on Economics and Computation 2(4), 1–37 (2014). \doi10.1145/2665005
- [15] Li, M., Lu, P., Yao, Y., Zhang, J.: Strategyproof Mechanism for Two Heterogeneous Facilities with Constant Approximation Ratio. In Proceedings of the 29th International Joint Conference on Artificial Intelligence, 238–245 (2020). \doi10.24963/ijcai.2020/34
- [16] Liu, W., Ding, Y., Chen, X., Fang, Q., Nong, Q.: Multiple facility location games with envy ratio. Theoretical Computer Science 864, 1–9 (2021). \doi10.1016/j.tcs.2021.01.016
- [17] Lu, P., Sun, X., Wang, Y., Zhu, Z. A.: Asymptotically optimal strategy-proof mechanisms for two-facility games. Proceedings of the 11th ACM conference on Electronic commerce, 315–324 (2010). \doi10.1145/1807342.1807393
- [18] Mei, L., Li, M., Ye, D., Zhang, G.: Facility location games with distinct desires. Discrete Applied Mathematics 264, 148–160 (2019). \doi10.1016/j.dam.2019.02.017
- [19] Moulin, H.: On strategy-proofness and single peakedness. Public Choice 35(4), 437–455 (1980). \doi10.1007/BF00128122
- [20] Procaccia, A. D., Tennenholtz, M.: Approximate mechanism design without money. In Proceedings of the 10th ACM conference on Electronic commerce, 177–186 (2009). \doi10.1145/1566374.1566401
- [21] Schummer, J., Vohra, R.: Strategy-proof location on a network. Journal of Economic Theory 104(2), 405–428 (2002). \doi10.1006/jeth.2001.2807
- [22] Serafino, P., Ventre, C.: Heterogeneous facility location without money. Theoretical Computer Science 636, 27–46 (2016). \doi10.1016/j.tcs.2016.04.033
- [23] Sui, X., Boutilier, C.: Approximately Strategy-proof Mechanisms for (Constrained) Facility Location. In Proceedings of the 14th international conference on autonomous agents and multiagent systems, 605–613 (2015)
- [24] Tang, Z., Wang, C., Zhang, M., Zhao, Y.: Mechanism design for facility location games with candidate locations. International Conference on Combinatorial Optimization and Applications, 440–452 (2020). \doi10.1007/978-3-030-64843-5_30
- [25] Xu, X., Li, B., Li, M., Duan, L.: Two-facility location games with minimum distance requirement. Journal of Artificial Intelligence Research 70, 719–756 (2021). \doi10.1613/jair.1.12319
- [26] Yuan, H., Wang, K., Fong, K. C., Zhang, Y., Li, M.: Facility location games with optional preference. Proceedings of the 22nd European Conference on Artificial Intelligence, 1520–1527 (2016). \doi10.3233/978-1-61499-672-9-1520
- [27] Zhang, Q., Li, M.: Strategyproof mechanism design for facility location games with weighted agents on a line. Journal of Combinatorial Optimization 28(4), 756–773 (2014). \doi10.1007/s10878-013-9598-8
- [28] Zhou, H., Li, M., Chan, H.: Strategyproof mechanisms for group-fair facility location problems. arXiv preprint arXiv:2107.05175 (2021)
- [29] Zou, S., Li, M.: Facility location games with dual preference. In Proceedings of the 14th international conference on autonomous agents and multiagent systems, 615–623 (2015)
Appendix 0.A Missing Proofs
0.A.1 Proof of Lemma 1
Proof
Given any , the set of agents can be divided into , , and .
To show group strategyproofness, we need to prove that for every nonempty with deviation , there exists who cannot benefit from the coalitional deviation. Denote and the mechanism by .
Case 1: . Then the cost of any agent cannot decrease by the deviation since is her favorite.
Case 2: . If , there must exist some agent who prefers the peak of to that of since , which implies that agent cannot benefit from the deviation. Similarly, if , there must exist some agent who prefers the peak of to that of since and cannot benefit from the deviation.
0.A.2 Proof of Lemma 2
Proof
Let be an optimal solution. Without loss of generality, assume that . Supposing there exists some such that , we only need to show that .
For each agent , , . If , obviously ; otherwise, .
Thus, we have
(3) | |||||
(4) | |||||
(5) | |||||
(6) |
0.A.3 Proof of Theorem 3.1
Proof
Suppose is a deterministic strategyproof mechanism with approximation ratio of for some .
Consider an instance with and , where is sufficiently small. can be , , , or and assume w.l.o.g. that or . Then the cost of agent 1 is .
For another instance with , it holds that and . If , , or , then . This implies that
(7) |
for sufficiently small , which is a contradiction. Thus, .
Note that . This indicates that agent 1 can decrease her cost by misreporting her location as , which contradicts ’s strategyproofness.
0.A.4 Proof of Theorem 3.2
Proof
By Lemma 1, Mechanism 1 is group strategyproof. We now turn to its approximation ratio.
Given a location profile , let be an optimal solution. Denote Mechanism 1 by and .
Considering that both and are adjacent location pairs in , assume w.l.o.g. that is on the right of .
Let be the location adjacent to the right of and be the right border of the zone of . We first give two claims, then compare with .
Claim 1. , since .
Claim 2. For any agent with , it holds that , since the peak of agent in is or to the left.
The sum cost of Mechanism 1 is
(8) | |||||
(9) |
where the first term is denoted by and the second by .
The optimal sum cost is
(10) | |||||
(11) |
where the first term is denoted by and the second by .
Note that
(12) | |||||
(13) | |||||
(14) | |||||
(15) | |||||
(16) | |||||
(17) |
Here, the third inequality holds by Claim 1. Besides, we have by Claim 2. Thus,
(18) |
Combining with Theorem 3.1, the approximation ratio of Mechanism 1 is 3.
0.A.5 Proof of Lemma 3
Proof
Let be the peak of in . If there exists , then
(19) |
If there exists , then
(20) |
Let be any feasible solution that is different from . Assume w.l.o.g. that , then either or . By symmetry, we only need to compare with through the following two cases.
Case 2: . In this case, . If , then and by Eq. (19), it holds that
(24) | |||||
(25) |
Thus, we have . Similarly if , then and . Thus, we have .
0.A.6 Proof of Theorem 3.3
Proof
Suppose is a deterministic strategyproof mechanism with approximation ratio of for some .
Consider an instance with and , where is sufficiently small. can be , , , or and assume w.l.o.g. that or . Then the cost of agent 1 is .
For another instance with , it holds that and . If , , or , then . This implies that
(26) |
for sufficiently small , which is a contradiction. Thus, .
Considering that , agent 1 can decrease her cost by misreporting her location as , which contradicts ’s strategyproofness.
0.A.7 Proof of Theorem 3.4
Proof
By Lemma 1, Mechanism 2 is group strategyproof. We now turn to its approximation ratio.
Given a location profile , let be the peak of in which is also an optimal solution. Denote Mechanism 2 by and . Assume without loss of generality that .
It is easy to see that , and
(27) |
We compare with through the following analysis.
Case 1: , or .
(28) |
Case 2: .
(29) |
Case 3: , or .
In this case, the right border of the zone of is no less than . Combining with the fact that lies in the zone of , it holds that also lies in the zone of . This implies that . Thus, we have
(30) |
Case 4: . Note that
(31) |
and
(32) |
Thus, it holds that
(33) |
Above all, . Combining with Theorem 3.3, Mechanism 2 has an approximation ratio of 3.
0.A.8 Proof of Theorem 4.1
Proof
Group strategyproofness. Given , Mechanism 3 outputs the facility location profile according to the public information . To show group strategyproofness, we need to prove that for every nonempty with deviation , there exists who cannot benefit from the coalitional deviation. Denote , Mechanism 3 by , Mechanism 1 by , and SC-Mechanism by .
Case 1: , then and . If , any agent in cannot benefit from the deviation by ’s group strategyproofness. If , , which implies that any agent in cannot benefit from the deviation.
Case 2: and . It holds that and , with and . If , any agent in cannot benefit from the deviation by ’s group strategyproofness. If , with . Still by ’s group strategyproofness, any agent in cannot benefit from the deviation .
Case 3: and . This case is similar to Case 2.
Approximation ratio. Given , let be an optimal solution and . We now compare with .
Case 1: If , the output of Mechanism 3 on equals to that of Mechanism 1 on . Denote the optimal solution on as .
By Theorem 3.2, it holds that
(34) |
Thus, we have
(35) | |||||
(36) | |||||
(38) | |||||
(39) | |||||
(40) |
Here, the above third inequality holds because for ,
(41) | |||||
(42) | |||||
(43) | |||||
(44) |
Case 2: If and . Without loss of generality, assume that . equals to the output of SC-Mechanism on instance , and equals to the output of SC-Mechanism on instance . Denote by the optimal solution on instance and the optimal solution on instance .
For , let , then
(45) | |||||
(46) |
For , by Proposition 1, it holds that
(47) |
For , we consider the following two cases.
Case 2.1: If , by Proposition 1, it holds that
(48) |
Case 2.2: , then and . On the one hand, by Proposition 1, we have
(49) |
On the other hand,
(50) | |||||
(51) | |||||
(52) | |||||
(53) |
where the first inequality holds because and the third holds by Eq. (47).
Case 3: and . This case is similar to Case 2.
Above all, Mechanism 3 has an approximation ratio of at most .
0.A.9 Proof of Theorem 4.2
Proof
The proof of Mechanism 4’s group strategyproofness is similar to that of Mechanism 3’s, which is omitted here. Now we focus on the approximation ratio of Mechanism 4.
Denote Mechanism 4 by . Given , let be an optimal solution and . We now compare with .
Case 1: If , the output of Mechanism 4 on equals to that of Mechanism 2 on . Denote by the optimal solution on .
By Theorem 3.4, it holds that
(58) |
Thus, we have
(59) | |||||
(60) | |||||
(61) | |||||
(63) | |||||
(65) | |||||
(66) |
Here, the above second inequality holds because for ,
(67) | |||||
(68) | |||||
(69) | |||||
(70) |
Case 2: . Assume w.l.o.g. that . equals to the output of MC-Mechanism on instance , and equals to the output of MC-Mechanism on instance . Denote by the optimal solution on instance and the optimal solution on instance .
For , let , then
(71) | |||||
(72) | |||||
(73) |
For , by Proposition 2, it holds that
(74) |
For , we consider the following two cases.
Case 2.1: If , by Proposition 2, it holds that
(75) |
Case 2.2: , then and . On the one hand, by Proposition 2, we have
(76) |
On the other hand,
(77) | |||||
(78) | |||||
(79) |
Above all, Mechanism 4 has an approximation ratio of at most .