This paper was converted on www.awesomepapers.org from LaTeX by an anonymous user.
Want to know more? Visit the Converter page.

Optional games on cycles and complete graphs

Hyeong-Chai Jeong111E-mail:hcj@sejong.ac.kr    Seung-Yoon Oh    Benjamin Allen    Martin A. Nowak Department of Physics, Sejong University, Gangjingu, Seoul 143-747, KOREA Program for Evolutionary Dynamics, Harvard University,Cambridge, MA 20138, USA Department of Mathematics, Emmanuel College, Boston, MA 02115 USA; Department of Mathematics, Harvard University,Cambridge, MA 20138, USA Department of Organismic and Evolutionary Biology, Harvard University,Cambridge, MA 20138, USA
Abstract

We study stochastic evolution of optional games on simple graphs. There are two strategies, A and B, whose interaction is described by a general payoff matrix. In addition there are one or several possibilities to opt out from the game by adopting loner strategies. Optional games lead to relaxed social dilemmas. Here we explore the interaction between spatial structure and optional games. We find that increasing the number of loner strategies (or equivalently increasing mutational bias toward loner strategies) facilitates evolution of cooperation both in well-mixed and in structured populations. We derive various limits for weak selection and large population size. For some cases we derive analytic results for strong selection. We also analyze strategy selection numerically for finite selection intensity and discuss combined effects of optionality and spatial structure.

keywords: Evolutionary game theory, Evolutionary graph theory, Evolution of cooperation, Spatial games

1 Introduction

In the typical setting of evolutionary game theory, the individual has to adopt one of several strategies (Hofbauer & Sigmund,, 1988; Weibull,, 1997; Friedman,, 1998; Hofbauer & Sigmund,, 1998; Cressman,, 2003; Nowak,, 2004; Vincent & Brown,, 2005; Gokhale & Traulsen,, 2011). For example in a standard cooperative dilemma (Hauert et al.,, 2006; Nowak,, 2012; Rand & Nowak,, 2013; Hauert et al.,, 2014), the individual can choose between cooperation and defection. Natural selection tends to oppose cooperation unless a mechanism for evolution of cooperation is at work (Nowak, 2006a, ). In optional games there is also the possibility not to play the game (Kitcher,, 1993; Batali & Kitcher,, 1995; Hauert et al.,, 2002; Hauert,, 2002; Szabó & Hauert, 2002a, ; De Silva et al.,, 2009; Rand & Nowak,, 2011). The individual player has to choose whether to participate in the game (by cooperating or defecting) or to opt out. Opting out leads to fixed “loner’s payoff”. This loner’s payoff is forfeited if one decides to play the game. Thus there is a cost for playing the game. Optional games tend to lead to relaxed social dilemmas (Michor & Nowak,, 2002; Hauert et al.,, 2006). They have also been used to study the effect of costly punishment (by peers and institutions) on evolution of cooperation (Boyd & Richerson,, 1992; Nakamaru & Iwasa,, 2005; Hauert et al.,, 2007; Sigmund,, 2007; Traulsen et al.,, 2009; Hilbe & Sigmund,, 2010). There is also a relationship between optional games and empty places in spatial settings (Nowak et al.,, 1994).

Here we study the effect of optional games on cycles and on complete graphs (van Veelen & Nowak,, 2012). Cycles and complete graphs are on opposite ends of the spectrum of spatial structure. Most graphs will lead to an evolutionary dynamics between these two extremes. Evolutionary graph theory (Lieberman et al.,, 2005; Santos & Pacheco,, 2005; Ohtsuki et al.,, 2006; Szabó & Fáth,, 2007; Fu et al., 2007a, ; Fu et al., 2007b, ; Santos et al.,, 2008; Perc & Szolnoki,, 2010; Perc,, 2011; Allen et al.,, 2013; Maciejewski,, 2014; Allen & Nowak,, 2014) is an approach to study the effect of population structure on evolutionary dynamics (Nowak & May,, 1992; Nakamaru et al.,, 1997; Tarnita et al., 2009b, ; Tarnita et al., 2009a, ; Nowak et al.,, 2010; Tarnita et al.,, 2011). Using stochastic evolutionary dynamics for games in finite populations (Foster & Young,, 1990; Challet & Zhang,, 1997; Taylor et al.,, 2004; Nowak et al.,, 2004; Imhof & Nowak,, 2006; Traulsen et al.,, 2006), we notice that the number of different loner strategies has an important effect on selection between strategies that occur in the game. Increasing the number of ways to opt out (or, increasing mutational bias toward (Garcia & Traulsen,, 2012) loner strategies) in general favors evolution of cooperation.

Our paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we give an overview of the basic model and list our key results. In Section 3 we calculate abundance in the low mutation limit. It is used to investigate the conditions for strategy selection in the weak selection limit in Section 4 and in the strong selection limit in Section 5. We calculate these conditions for optional games with simplified prisoner’s dilemma games in Section 6. We then analyze strategy selection numerically for finite mutation rate as well as finite selection intensity in low mutation in Section 7. In our concluding remarks in Section 8, we summarize and discuss the implications of our findings.

2 Model and main results

We consider stochastic evolutionary dynamics of populations on graphs. In particular, we investigate the condition for one strategy to be favored over the others in the limit of low mutation and for two different reproduction processes, birth-death (BD) updating and death-birth (DB) updating on cycles. We compare the results with those for the Moran Process (MP) on the complete graph. The fitness of an individual is determined by the payoff from the non-repeated matrix games with its nearest neighbors. We use exponential fitness,

fr\displaystyle f_{r} =\displaystyle= ewPr,\displaystyle e^{wP_{r}}, (1)

for the individual at the site rr, where PrP_{r} is its accumulated payoff from the games with its neighbors. The intensity of selection, ww, is a parameter representing how strongly the fitness of an individual depends on the its payoff.

We first study a general matrix game whose payoff matrix is given by A=[aij]A=[\,a_{ij}\,], i.e., a game that an individual using strategy SiS_{i} receives aija_{ij} as a payoff when it plays with an individual with strategy SjS_{j}. Then we apply our finding to an optional prisoner’s dilemma game to find a condition for evolution of cooperation.

We calculate abundance (frequencies in the stationary distribution) of strategies in the low mutation limit, where mutation rate uu goes to zero, and find the condition that strategy SiS_{i} is more abundant than strategy SjS_{j}. For low mutation, abundance can be written in terms of fixation probabilities which we obtain in a closed form for general ww. Although the formal expression of abundance is useful for numerical calculation, the complexity of the expression makes it hard for us to understand the strategy selection mechanism intuitively.

For low intensity of selection (w0w\rightarrow 0), however, the fixation probability reduces to a linear expression in aija_{ij} with clear interpretation. The condition for strategy selection is then given by a simple linear inequality in terms of payoff matrix elements. This is the case even for the large population limit of NN\rightarrow\infty.

However, when considering the limits of weak selection (w0w\to 0) and large population (NN\to\infty), the condition for strategy selection depends on the order in which these limits are taken. We therefore consider two different large population, weak selection limits: the wNwN limit and the NwNw imit. In the wNwN limit, ww goes to zero before NN goes to infinity such that NwNw is much smaller than 1. In the NwNw limit, NN goes to infinity before ww goes to zero such that NwNw is much larger than 1.

2.1 wNwN limit

We first calculate the fixation probability, ρik\rho_{ik}, which is the probability that a singe SiS_{i} takes over the whole population of the strategy SkS_{k} for the w0w\rightarrow 0 limit. It can be written as

ρik\displaystyle\rho_{ik} =\displaystyle= 1N+dikw.\displaystyle\frac{1}{N}+d_{ik}\,w. (2)

Here, the “biased drift”, dikd_{ik} is defined by

dik\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054ptd_{ik} =\displaystyle= {12lik12NsikforBD14lik14NsikforDB14lik112sikforMP\displaystyle\left\{\begin{array}[]{ll}\frac{1}{2}\,l_{ik}-\frac{1}{2N}\,s_{ik}&\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{BD}\\ \frac{1}{4}\,l_{ik}-\frac{1}{4N}\,s_{ik}&\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{DB}\\ \frac{1}{4}\,l_{ik}-\frac{1}{12}\,s_{ik}&\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{MP}\end{array}\right. (6)

with the anti-symmetric term likl_{ik} and the symmetric term siks_{ik} given by

lik\displaystyle l_{ik} =\displaystyle= σNaii+aikakiσNakk\displaystyle\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}a_{ii}+a_{ik}-a_{ki}-\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}a_{kk}
sik\displaystyle s_{ik} =\displaystyle= σN(aiiaikaki+akk).\displaystyle\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}\left({a_{ii}-a_{ik}-a_{ki}+a_{kk}}\right). (7)

The structure factor, σN\sigma_{\!{}_{N}} for the population of the size NN, is given by

σN\displaystyle\sigma_{\!{}_{N}} =\displaystyle= {12/NforBD &  MP38/NforDB.\displaystyle\left\{\begin{array}[]{ll}1-2/N&\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{BD\ \& \ MP}\\ 3-8/N&\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{DB}.\end{array}\right. (10)

Using fixation probabilities of Eq. (2), we then calculate abundance in the low mutation limit and show that strategy SiS_{i} is more abundant than strategy SjS_{j} when

klik\displaystyle\sum_{k}\,l_{ik} >\displaystyle> kljk\displaystyle\sum_{k}\,l_{jk} (11)

as previously known (Nowak et al.,, 2010; Ohtsuki & Nowak,, 2006). The fixation probability obtained for a general 2×22\times 2 matrix game is also applied to calculate abundance of cooperator and defectors in optional prisoner’s dilemma game(Szabó & Hauert, 2002b, ) with (n+2)(n+2) strategies, cooperator (C), defector (D) and nn different types of loners, L1,,LnL_{1},\cdots,L_{n}. The payoff matrix is given by

CDL1LnCDL1Ln(RSggTPgggggggggg).\displaystyle\hskip-28.45274pt\begin{array}[]{cl}\mbox{}&\begin{array}[]{ccccc}\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636ptC&\mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pt\ \ D&\mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pt\ \ L_{1}&\ \cdots&\ L_{n}\end{array}\\ \begin{array}[]{c}C\\ D\\ L_{1}\\ \vdots\\ L_{n}\end{array}&\left(\begin{array}[]{ccccc}\mbox{}\hskip 2.84526ptR&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636ptS&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636ptg&\mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pt\cdots&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636ptg\\ \mbox{}\hskip 2.84526ptT&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636ptP&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636ptg&\mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pt\cdots&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636ptg\\ \mbox{}\hskip 2.84526ptg&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636ptg&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636ptg&\mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pt\cdots&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636ptg\\ \mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pt\vdots&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636pt\vdots&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636pt\vdots&\mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pt\ddots&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636pt\vdots\\ \mbox{}\hskip 2.84526ptg&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636ptg&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636ptg&\mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pt\cdots&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636ptg\\ \end{array}\right).\end{array} (25)

When two cooperators meet, both get payoff RR. When two defectors meet, they get payoff PP. If a cooperator meets a defector, the defector gets the payoff TT while the cooperator get the payoff SS. Loners get payoff gg always. Cooperators or defectors also get payoff gg when they meet a loner. Since the nn different types of loners have the same payoff structure, this system is equivalent to to the population with three strategies, CC, DD, and a single type of loners, LL if the mutation rate toward LL (from CC or DD) is nn times larger than the other way.

In the limit of ww goes to zero, we find that the condition for xC>xDx_{\!{}_{C}}>x_{\!{}_{D}} is given as

σN(n)R+S\displaystyle\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}(n)\,R+S >\displaystyle> T+σN(n)P,\displaystyle T+\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}(n)\,P, (26)

where

σN(n)\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}(n)\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt =\displaystyle= {(1+12n)(12N)forBD & MP(1+12n)(38N)forDB.\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\left\{\begin{array}[]{lll}\left({1+\frac{1}{2}\,n}\right)\left({1-\frac{2}{N}}\right)\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt&\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{BD\ \& MP}\\ \left({1+\frac{1}{2}\,n}\right)\left({3-\frac{8}{N}}\right)\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt&\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{DB}.\end{array}\right. (29)

As long as ww goes to zero first (Nw1Nw\ll 1), inequality (26) is valid even in the large population limit of NN\rightarrow\infty, where the structure factor, σN(n)\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}(n) becomes

σ(n)\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\sigma(n)\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt =\displaystyle= {1+12nforBD & MP3+32nforDB.\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\left\{\begin{array}[]{lll}1+\frac{1}{2}\,n&\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{BD\ \& MP}\\ 3+\frac{3}{2}\,n&\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{DB}.\end{array}\right. (32)

If we do not allow any loner type, then n=0n=0 and σN(n)\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}(n) becomes σN\sigma_{\!{}_{N}} of Eq. (10) as expected, and cooperators are more abundant than defectors if and only if ρCD>ρDC\rho_{\!{}_{CD}}>\rho_{\!{}_{DC}}. On the other hand, when the number of loner types, nn, goes to infinity, σ\sigma becomes infinity and social dilemmas are completely resolved. Cooperators are more abundant than defectors whenever R>PR>P.

2.2 Nw limit

We still consider the low selection intensity limit (w0w\rightarrow 0) but we take the large population limit first such that NwNw is much larger than 1. In this case, we can calculate the fixation probability analytically only for BD and DB. Fixation of SiS_{i} (invading strategy SkS_{k}) is possible only when likl_{ik} is positive where

lik\displaystyle l_{ik} =\displaystyle= σaii+aikakiσakk.\displaystyle\sigma a_{ii}+a_{ik}-a_{ki}-\sigma a_{kk}. (33)

The structure factor for infinite population, σ\sigma in Eq. (33) is 1 for BD and 3 for DB. When likl_{ik} is positive, fixation probability, ρik\rho_{ik} is proportional to likl_{ik} and given by

ρik\displaystyle\rho_{ik} =\displaystyle= {likΘ(lik)forBD12likΘ(lik)forDB,\displaystyle\left\{\begin{array}[]{ll}\,l_{ik}\,\Theta(l_{ik})&\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{BD}\\ \frac{1}{2}l_{ik}\,\Theta(l_{ik})&\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{DB},\end{array}\right. (36)

where Θ(x)\Theta(x) is the Heaviside step function.

We calculate abundance for the low mutation limit using fixation probabilities given by Eq. (36) for a general 3 strategy game and find conditions for the abundance xix_{i} of strategy SiS_{i} to be larger than the abundance xjx_{j} of strategy SjS_{j}. Here ii, jj, and kk are the indices representing three distinct strategies, SiS_{i}, SjS_{j}, and SkS_{k}. If both lijl_{ij} and likl_{ik} are positive, SjS_{j} and SkS_{k} cannot invade SiS_{i} and we have xi=1x_{i}=1 and xj=xk=0x_{j}=x_{k}=0, i.e., xi>xjx_{i}>x_{j} always. By the same token, xix_{i} cannot be larger than xjx_{j} when both ljil_{ji} and ljkl_{jk} are positive. If lkil_{ki} and lkjl_{kj} are positive, both xix_{i} and xjx_{j} are zero. The only non-trivial case is when three strategies, show rock-paper-scissors-like characteristics in terms of lijl_{ij}. For the lij>0l_{ij}>0 case (with ljk>0l_{jk}>0 and lki>0l_{ki}>0), strategy SiS_{i} is more abundant than strategy SjS_{j} when lij>lkil_{ij}>l_{ki}. For the lji>0l_{ji}>0 case (with lik>0l_{ik}>0 and lkj>0l_{kj}>0), strategy SiS_{i} is more abundant than strategy SjS_{j} when lji<lkjl_{ji}<l_{kj}.

The analysis for three strategy game can be applied to optional prisoner’s game with nn types of loners whose payoff matrix is given by Eq. (25). The condition for xC>xDx_{\!{}_{C}}>x_{\!{}_{D}} can be still written as a linear inequality but the coefficients of the linear inequality depend on the signs of RPR-P, RgR-g, and PgP-g. For simplicity, we first assume that R>PR>P without loss of generality. Then, when P>gP>g, the condition for xC>xDx_{\!{}_{C}}>x_{\!{}_{D}} becomes

R+S>T+PforBD3R+S>T+3PforDB.\displaystyle\begin{array}[]{llll}\ R+S&>&T+\ P&\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{BD}\\ 3R+S&>&T+3P&\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{DB}.\end{array} (39)

For the other case of P<gP<g, the condition for xC>xDx_{\!{}_{C}}>x_{\!{}_{D}} becomes

R+S>T+P+n(Pg)forBD3R+S>T+3P+3n(Pg)forDB.\displaystyle\begin{array}[]{llll}\ R+S&>&T+\ P+\ n(P-g)&\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{BD}\\ 3R+S&>&T+3P+3n(P-g)&\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{DB}.\end{array} (42)

For high intensity of selection (w1w\gg 1), strategy selection strongly depends on the number of loner strategies, nn. If nn is larger than 1, cooperators are more abundant than defectors as long as g>Pg>P. On the other hands, for n=1n=1, the condition for xC>xDx_{\!{}_{C}}>x_{\!{}_{D}} depends on the reproduction processes. For n=1n=1, we obtain the condition only for the “simplified” prisoner’s dilemma game (“donation game”) in which the payoffs are described in terms of the benefit, bb and the cost, cc of cooperation, R=bcR=b-c, S=cS=-c, T=bT=b, P=0P=0. For BD, cooperators are always less abundant than defectors as long as g<bg<b. For DB and MP, xCx_{\!{}_{C}} is larger than xDx_{\!{}_{D}} if

c<b/2forDBc<gforMP.\displaystyle\begin{array}[]{llll}c&<&b/2&\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{DB}\\ c&<&g&\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{MP}.\end{array} (45)

2.3 Numerical analysis

Our analytic results are obtained in the two extreme limits of selection strength (w0w\to 0 and ww\to\infty) in the zero mutation limit. For finite values of ww (with low mutation rate), we solve conditions for xC>xDx_{\!{}_{C}}>x_{\!{}_{D}} numerically, using calculated abundance from fixation probabilities. For finite mutation rates, we perform a series of Monte Carlo simulations and measure abundance to obtain the condition for strategy selection.

In particular, we consider a simplified prisoner’s dilemma game with one type of loners (n=1n=1) in which the analytic conditions for xC>xDx_{\!{}_{C}}>x_{\!{}_{D}} [inequalities (26), (39) and (42)] become

c<N65N6bforBD & MPc<7N2411N24bforDB,\displaystyle\begin{array}[]{llll}c&<&\frac{N-6}{5N-6}\,b&\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{BD\ \& MP}\\ c&<&\frac{7N-24}{11N-24}\,b&\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{DB},\end{array} (48)

for the wNwN limit, and

g>2cforBDg>43(cb/2)forDB,\displaystyle\begin{array}[]{llll}g&>&2c&\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{BD}\\ g&>&\frac{4}{3}\left({c-b/2}\right)&\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{DB},\end{array} (51)

for the NwNw limit.

We first confirm these conditions numerically with a finite but small ww in the low mutation limit. Abundance of each strategy is calculated for Nw=0.01Nw=0.01 and Nw=100Nw=100 (with N=104N=10^{4}). We find more cooperators than defectors when inequality (48) is satisfied for Nw=0.01Nw=0.01 and inequality (51) for Nw=100Nw=100. When NwNw is much smaller than 1, cooperators in BD and those in MP are more abundant than defectors in the same region in the parameter space as inequality (48) predicts. However, they are different for general NwNw. When NwNw is much larger than 1, cooperators are less abundant than defectors always for BD but we find more cooperators than defectors when g>cg>c for MP.

For finite mutation rate, we investigate abundance by Monte Carlo simulation. We start from a random arrangement of three strategies on a cycle (BD and DB) or a complete graph (MP) with N=50N=50 sites. Population evolves with BD, DB, or MP updating processes with the mutation rate, u=0.0002u=0.0002. We monitor the time evolution of the average frequencies and see if the population evolves to a steady state in which average frequency remains constant. We measure abundance, the frequency average in the steady state, and find that abundance in our simulations agrees quite well with calculations in the low mutation limits using fixation probabilities.

3 Derivation of general expressions for fixation probability and abundance

We now begin our derivation of the results presented above. We begin by obtaining general expressions for fixation probability and abundance that are valid for any population size and selection intensity. These expressions are obtained first for a general 3×33\times 3 matrix game, and then for the optional prisoners’ dilemma game.

When there are mutations, the population will not evolve to an absorbing state of one kind. Yet, in many cases, it is expected for them to evolve to a steady state in which the frequency of each type (in a sufficiently large population) stays constant. We use the term “abundance” for frequency in the steady state. For a small population, frequencies may oscillate with time through mutation-fixation cycles, especially when the mutation rate is very small. In this case, abundance is defined as the time average of frequencies over fixation cycles.

In this section, we consider abundance in the low mutation limit, in which the mutation rate uu goes to zero. We imagine an invasion of a mutant in the mono-strategy population and we ignore the possibility of further mutation during the fixation sweep. In this low mutation limit, abundance can be expressed in terms of fixation probabilities. We first calculate fixation probabilities for general selection intensity ww and present them in a closed form for BD and DB. Then, we present abundance in terms of fixation probabilities.

3.1 Fixation probability

We consider the fixation probability of A (invading a population that consists of B) for a general 2x2 matrix game with the payoff matrix,

ABAB(abcd).\begin{array}[]{cl}&\begin{array}[]{cc}\mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pt\ \ A&\mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pt\ \ B\mbox{}\end{array}\\ \begin{array}[]{c}A\\ B\end{array}&\left(\begin{array}[]{cc}a&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636ptb\\ c&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636ptd\end{array}\right).\end{array}

In general, the fixation probability of AA is given by

ρAB\displaystyle\rho_{\!{}_{AB}} =\displaystyle= [1+m=1N1NA=1mTNATNA+]1\displaystyle\left[{1+\sum_{m=1}^{N-1}\prod_{{N_{\!A}}=1}^{m}\frac{T_{N_{\!A}}^{-}}{T_{N_{\!A}}^{+}}}\right]^{-1} (52)

where TNA±T_{N_{\!A}}^{\pm} is the probability that the number of A becomes NA±1{N_{\!A}}\pm 1 from NA{N_{\!A}} (Nowak, 2006b, ). When new offspring appear in nearest neighbor sites, as they do for BD and DB, only one connected cluster of invaders can form on a cycle and TNA±T_{N_{\!A}}^{\pm} can be easily calculated. In fact, with exponential fitness, ρAB\rho_{\!{}_{AB}} is given in a closed form.

For BD, the fixation probability can be written in the form of

ρAB\displaystyle\rho_{\!{}_{AB}} =\displaystyle= fg+hyN,\displaystyle\frac{f}{g\ +\ h\,y^{N}}, (53)

with

f\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054ptf\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt =\displaystyle= ew(a+b)ew(c+d)\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pte^{w(a+b)}-e^{w(c+d)}
g\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054ptg\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt =\displaystyle= ew(a+b)ew(c+d)+ew(ab+c+d)\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pte^{w(a+b)}-e^{w(c+d)}+e^{w(a-b+c+d)}
h\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pth\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt =\displaystyle= ew(2ac2d)[ew(a+b+c)ew(a+b+d)ew(2c+d)]\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pte^{w(2a-c-2d)}\left[{e^{w(a+b+c)}-e^{w(a+b+d)}-e^{w(2c+d)}}\right]
y\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pty\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt =\displaystyle= ew(c+dab),\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pte^{w(c+d-a-b)}, (54)

when a+bc+da+b\not=c+d. Note that both denominator and numerator of the right hand side of Eq. (53) are zero when a+b=c+da+b=c+d. For this singular case, ρAB\rho_{\!{}_{AB}} can be directly calculated from Eq. (52) and is given by

ρAB\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\rho_{\!{}_{AB}}\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt =\displaystyle= 11+e2w(bc)2ew(ab)+New(ab).\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\frac{1}{1\ +e^{2w(b-c)}-2\,e^{w(a-b)}+N\,e^{w(a-b)}}. (55)

In the limit of a+bc+da+b\rightarrow c+d, Eq. (53) [with Eq. (54)] becomes identical to Eq. (55). Hence, we can write the fixation probability of A for BD on a cycle as Eq. (53) for general case if it is understood as the limiting value when both denominator and numerator becomes zero.

For DB, the fixation probability can be also written in the form of Eq. (53) but now with

f\displaystyle\hskip-14.22636ptf =\displaystyle= ew(3a+b)ew(c+3d)\displaystyle e^{w(3a+b)}-e^{w(c+3d)}\mbox{}\hskip 42.67912pt
g\displaystyle\hskip-14.22636ptg =\displaystyle= (ew(3a+b)ew(c+3d))3+e2w(db)2\displaystyle\left({e^{w(3a+b)}-e^{w(c+3d)}}\right)\frac{3+e^{2w(d-b)}}{2}
+ew(c+d)(e2wb+e2wd)(ew(a+b)+e2wd)(e2wa+ew(c+d))2e2wb(ew(a+b)+ew(c+d))\displaystyle+\,\frac{e^{w(c+d)}\left({e^{2wb}+e^{2wd}}\right)\left({e^{w(a+b)}+e^{2wd}}\right)\left({e^{2wa}+e^{w(c+d)}}\right)}{2e^{2wb}\left({e^{w(a+b)}+e^{w(c+d)}}\right)}
h\displaystyle\hskip-14.22636pth =\displaystyle= [ew(3a+b)(e2wb+e2wd)(e2wa+ew(c+d))4]\displaystyle\left[{e^{w(3a+b)}\left({e^{2wb}+e^{2wd}}\right)\left({e^{2wa}+e^{w(c+d)}}\right)^{4}}\right]
×[(e2wa+3e2wc)(ew(c+3d)ew(3a+b))2e3w(c+d)(ew(a+b)+e2wd)4(e2wa+e2wc)]\displaystyle\times\left[{\frac{\left({e^{2wa}+3e^{2wc}}\right)\left({e^{w(c+3d)}-e^{w(3a+b)}}\right)}{2e^{3w(c+d)}\left({e^{w(a+b)}+e^{2wd}}\right)^{4}\left({e^{2wa}+e^{2wc}}\right)}}\right]
e2w(2a+b)(e2wb+e2wd)(e2wa+ew(c+d))52e3w(c+d)(ew(a+b)+e2wd)3(ew(a+b)+ew(c+d))\displaystyle-\,\frac{e^{2w(2a+b)}\left({e^{2wb}+e^{2wd}}\right)\left({e^{2wa}+e^{w(c+d)}}\right)^{5}}{2e^{3w(c+d)}\left({e^{w(a+b)}+e^{2wd}}\right)^{3}\left({e^{w(a+b)}+e^{w(c+d)}}\right)}
y\displaystyle\hskip-14.22636pty =\displaystyle= ew(3a+bc3d)+ew(c+d2a)1+ew(c+d2a),\displaystyle\frac{e^{-w(3a+b-c-3d)}+e^{w(c+d-2a)}}{1\ +\ e^{w(c+d-2a)}}, (56)

when 3a+bc+3d3a+b\not=c+3d. We can also show that Eq. (53) [with Eq. (56)] becomes the fixation probability for 3a+b=c+3d3a+b=c+3d if we take the limit of 3a+bc+3d3a+b\rightarrow c+3d.

For MP, the fixation probability given by Eq. (52) cannot be written in a closed form in general but reduces (Traulsen et al.,, 2008) to

ρAB\displaystyle\hskip-17.07164pt\rho_{\!{}_{AB}}\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt =\displaystyle= (m=1N1ew[(abc+d)2(N1)m(m+1)(abN+dNd)N1m])1.\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\left({\sum_{m=1}^{N-1}e^{-w\left[{\frac{(a-b-c+d)}{2(N-1)}\,m(m+1)-\frac{(a-bN+dN-d)}{N-1}\,m}\right]}}\right)^{-1}. (57)

For a+d=b+ca+d=b+c, the summation in Eq. (57) can be calculated exactly and we have

ρAB\displaystyle\hskip-17.07164pt\rho_{\!{}_{AB}}\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt =\displaystyle= ew(abN+dNd)/(N1)1ewN(abN+dNd)/(N1)1.\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\frac{e^{w(a-bN+dN-d)/(N-1)}-1}{e^{wN(a-bN+dN-d)/(N-1)}-1}. (58)

For a+db+ca+d\not=b+c, the summation can be approximated by an integral (Traulsen et al.,, 2008) and we have

ρAB\displaystyle\hskip-17.07164pt\rho_{\!{}_{AB}}\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt \displaystyle\approx erf(wu[u+v])erf(wuv)erf(wu[uN+v])erf(wuv).\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\frac{{\rm erf}\Big{(}\,{\sqrt{w\over u}\,[u+v]}\,\Big{)}-{\rm erf}\Big{(}\,{\sqrt{w\over u}\,v}\,\Big{)}}{{\rm erf}\Big{(}\,{\sqrt{w\over u}\,[uN+v]}\,\Big{)}-{\rm erf}\Big{(}\,{\sqrt{w\over u}\,v}\,\Big{)}}. (59)

Here, u=(abc+d)/(2N2)u=(a-b-c+d)/(2N-2), v=(a+bNdN+d)/(2N2)v=(-a+bN-dN+d)/(2N-2) and erf(x)=2π0xey2𝑑y{\rm erf}(x)=\frac{2}{\sqrt{\pi}}\,\int_{0}^{x}e^{-y^{2}}\,dy is the error function. The summation in Eq. (57) can be also calculated exactly for the wNwN limit (see Section 4) where the exponential term can be linearized.

3.2 Abundance in the low mutation limit

Let xix_{i} be the abundance of strategy SiS_{i}, whose payoff matrix is given by

S1S2S3S1S2S3(a11a12a13a21a22a23a31a32a33).\displaystyle\begin{array}[]{cl}\mbox{}&\begin{array}[]{ccc}\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636ptS_{1}&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636pt\ \ S_{2}&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636pt\ \ S_{3}\end{array}\\ \begin{array}[]{c}S_{1}\\ S_{2}\\ S_{3}\end{array}&\left(\begin{array}[]{ccc}\mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pta_{11}&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636pta_{12}&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636pta_{13}\\ \mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pta_{21}&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636pta_{22}&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636pta_{23}\\ \mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pta_{31}&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636pta_{32}&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636pta_{33}\end{array}\right).\end{array} (69)

Then, in the low mutation limit, we expect the abundance vector, x=(x1,x2,x3)\vec{x}=(x_{1},x_{2},x_{3}) can be written as

x\displaystyle\vec{x} =\displaystyle= xT,\displaystyle\vec{x}\,T, (70)

with the transfer matrix

T\displaystyle T =\displaystyle= (1ρ21ρ31ρ21ρ31ρ121ρ12ρ32ρ32ρ13ρ231ρ13ρ23).\displaystyle\begin{pmatrix}1-\rho_{21}-\rho_{31}&\rho_{21}&\rho_{31}\\ \rho_{12}&1-\rho_{12}-\rho_{32}&\rho_{32}\\ \rho_{13}&\rho_{23}&1-\rho_{13}-\rho_{23}\end{pmatrix}.

Here, ρij\rho_{ij} is the fixation probability of strategy SiS_{i} (invading the population of strategy SjS_{j}). A (unnormalized) left eigen-vector of TT with the unit eigen value, xu=(x1u,x2u,x3u)\vec{x}^{u}=(x_{1}^{u},x_{2}^{u},x_{3}^{u}) is given by

x1u\displaystyle x_{1}^{u} =\displaystyle= ρ12ρ13+ρ13ρ32+ρ12ρ23\displaystyle\rho_{12}\rho_{13}\,+\,\rho_{13}\rho_{32}+\rho_{12}\rho_{23}
x2u\displaystyle x_{2}^{u} =\displaystyle= ρ23ρ21+ρ21ρ13+ρ23ρ31\displaystyle\rho_{23}\rho_{21}\,+\,\rho_{21}\rho_{13}+\rho_{23}\rho_{31}
x3u\displaystyle x_{3}^{u} =\displaystyle= ρ31ρ32+ρ32ρ21+ρ31ρ12.\displaystyle\rho_{31}\rho_{32}\,+\,\rho_{32}\rho_{21}+\rho_{31}\rho_{12}. (71)

Once we calculate all fixation probabilities ρij\rho_{ij}, the steady state frequencies, xix_{i} can be obtained by normalizing xiux_{i}^{u};

xi\displaystyle x_{i} =\displaystyle= xiu/jxju.\displaystyle x_{i}^{u}\,/\,\sum_{j}x_{j}^{u}. (72)

3.3 Optional prisoner’s dilemma game

The fixation probabilities obtained in Section 3.1 can be used to calculate abundance of cooperators and defectors in optional prisoner’s dilemma game. Here, we consider the game with (n+2)(n+2) strategies, cooperator (C), defector (D) and nn different loners, L1,,LnL_{1},\cdots,L_{n} whose payoff matrix is given by Eq. (25). We introduce nn different types of loners to investigate how the condition for the emergence of cooperation varies with the number of loner types, nn.

Let xCx_{\!{}_{C}}, xDx_{\!{}_{D}}, and xLjx_{\!{}_{L_{j}}} be the abundance of CC, DD, and LjL_{j}, respectively. Then, for low mutation, the abundance vector x~=(xC,xD,xL1,,xLn)\tilde{\vec{x}}=(x_{\!{}_{C}},x_{\!{}_{D}},x_{\!{}_{L_{1}}},\cdots,x_{\!{}_{L_{n}}}) can be written as

x~\displaystyle\tilde{\vec{x}} =\displaystyle= x~T~\displaystyle\tilde{\vec{x}}\,\tilde{T} (73)

with

T~\displaystyle\tilde{T} =\displaystyle= (T~CCρDCρL1CρLnCρCDT~DDρL1DρLnDρCL1ρDL1T~L1L1ρLnL1ρCLnρDLnρL1LnT~LnLn).\displaystyle\begin{pmatrix}\tilde{T}_{CC}\mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pt&\rho_{\!{}_{DC}}\mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pt&\rho_{\!{}_{L_{1}C}}&\cdots&\rho_{\!{}_{L_{n}C}}\\ \rho_{\!{}_{CD}}\mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pt&\tilde{T}_{DD}\mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pt&\rho_{\!{}_{L_{1}D}}&\cdots&\rho_{\!{}_{L_{n}D}}\\ \rho_{\!{}_{CL_{1}}}\mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pt&\rho_{\!{}_{DL_{1}}}\mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pt&\tilde{T}_{L_{1}L_{1}}&\cdots&\rho_{\!{}_{L_{n}L_{1}}}\\ \mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pt\vdots\mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pt&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636pt\vdots\mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pt&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636pt\vdots&\mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pt\ddots&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636pt\vdots\\ \rho_{\!{}_{CL_{n}}}\mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pt&\rho_{\!{}_{DL_{n}}}\mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pt&\rho_{\!{}_{L_{1}L_{n}}}&\cdots&\tilde{T}_{L_{n}L_{n}}\end{pmatrix}. (74)

As before, ρij\rho_{ij} is the fixation probability that an SiS_{i} takes over the population of SjS_{j} and T~ii=1jiρij\tilde{T}_{ii}=1-\sum_{j\not=i}\rho_{ij} with the convention that strategy 1 is C, strategy 2 is D, and strategy SiS_{i} is Li2L_{i-2} for i>2i>2. Since the payoffs of the games involving loners are independent of the loner type, so are the fixation probabilities involving LjL_{j}. By denoting ρiLj\rho_{\!{}_{iL_{j}}} by ρiL\rho_{\!{}_{iL}}, Eqs. (73) and (74) can be rewritten in terms of the total frequency of loners xL=jxLjx_{\!{}_{L}}=\sum_{j}x_{\!{}_{L_{j}}} as

x\displaystyle\vec{x} =\displaystyle= xT\displaystyle\vec{x}\,T (75)

with x=(xC,xD,xL)\vec{x}=(x_{\!{}_{C}},x_{\!{}_{D}},x_{\!{}_{L}}), where

T\displaystyle T =\displaystyle= (1ρDCnρLCρDCnρLCρCD1ρCDnρLDnρLDρCLρDL1ρCLρDL).\displaystyle\begin{pmatrix}1-\rho_{\!{}_{DC}}-n\rho_{\!{}_{LC}}\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt&\rho_{\!{}_{DC}}&n\rho_{\!{}_{LC}}\\ \rho_{\!{}_{CD}}&\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt1-\rho_{\!{}_{CD}}-n\rho_{\!{}_{LD}}&n\rho_{\!{}_{LD}}\\ \rho_{\!{}_{CL}}&\rho_{\!{}_{DL}}&\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt1-\rho_{\!{}_{CL}}-\rho_{\!{}_{DL}}\end{pmatrix}. (76)

The evolution dynamics of Eq. (75) with the transfer matrix, TT of Eq. (76) can be interpreted as biasing the mutation rate toward loner strategies. The mutation rate toward LL (from CC or DD) is nn times larger than the other way.

The abundance vector of three strategies, C, D, and L, is proportional to the left eigen-vectors of TT with the unit eigen value, xu=(xCu,xDu,xLu)\vec{x}^{u}=(x_{\!{}_{C}}^{u},x_{\!{}_{D}}^{u},x_{\!{}_{L}}^{u}), given by

xCu\displaystyle x_{\!{}_{C}}^{u} =\displaystyle= ρCDρCL+nρCLρLD+ρCDρDL\displaystyle\ \ \rho_{\!{}_{CD}}\rho_{\!{}_{CL}}\,+n\,\rho_{\!{}_{CL}}\rho_{\!{}_{LD}}+\ \ \rho_{\!{}_{CD}}\rho_{\!{}_{DL}}
xDu\displaystyle x_{\!{}_{D}}^{u} =\displaystyle= ρDLρDC+ρDCρCL+nρDLρLC\displaystyle\ \ \rho_{\!{}_{DL}}\rho_{\!{}_{DC}}\,+\ \ \rho_{\!{}_{DC}}\rho_{\!{}_{CL}}+n\,\rho_{\!{}_{DL}}\rho_{\!{}_{LC}}
xLu\displaystyle x_{\!{}_{L}}^{u} =\displaystyle= n2ρLCρLD+nρLDρDC+nρLCρCD.\displaystyle n^{2}\rho_{\!{}_{LC}}\rho_{\!{}_{LD}}+n\,\rho_{\!{}_{LD}}\rho_{\!{}_{DC}}+n\,\rho_{\!{}_{LC}}\rho_{\!{}_{CD}}. (77)

Here ρCD\rho_{\!{}_{CD}}, ρCL\rho_{\!{}_{CL}}, \ldots are fixation probabilities between three strategies with payoff matrix,

CDLCDL(RSgTPgggg).\displaystyle\begin{array}[]{cl}&\begin{array}[]{ccc}\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636ptC&\mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pt\ \ D&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636ptL\end{array}\\ \begin{array}[]{c}C\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\\ D\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\\ L\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\end{array}&\left(\begin{array}[]{ccc}R&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636ptS&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636pt\ g\\ T&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636ptP&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636pt\ g\\ g&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636ptg&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636pt\ g\end{array}\right).\end{array} (87)

4 Analysis of the wNwN limit

We now consider the results of Section 3 under the wNwN limit. This limit is obtained by taking the w0w\to 0 limit for fixed NN, and then taking the NN\to\infty limit of the result. We calculate abundance in terms of fixation probabilities in the wNwN limit and analyze the condition for the cooperators are more abundant than defectors.

4.1 Fixation probability

As ww goes to zero, the fixation probability for BD, Eq. (53) [with Eq. (54)] becomes

ρAB\displaystyle\rho_{\!{}_{AB}} =\displaystyle= 1N+w2N2[(N23N+2)a+(N2+N2)b]\displaystyle\frac{1}{N}\,+\,\frac{w}{2N^{2}}\Big{[}\,{\left({N^{2}-3N+2}\right)a+\left({N^{2}+N-2}\right)b}\,\Big{]} (88)
w2N2[(N2N+2)c+(N2N2)d]\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636pt-\,\frac{w}{2N^{2}}\Big{[}\,{\left({N^{2}-N+2}\right)c+\left({N^{2}-N-2}\right)d}\,\Big{]}
=\displaystyle= 1N+w2[(σNa+bcσNd)σNN(abc+d)],\displaystyle\frac{1}{N}+\frac{w}{2}\Big{[}\,{\left({\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}a+b-c-\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}d}\right)-\frac{\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}}{N}\left({a-b-c+d}\right)}\,\Big{]},

where σN=12/N\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}=1-2/N. In the second line, we divide the ww dependent parts as the sum of the anti-symmetric term and the symmetric term under exchange of A and B. The symmetric term contributes equally to both ρAB\rho_{\!{}_{AB}} and ρBA\rho_{\!{}_{BA}} and is irrelevant to determine abundance. For DB, the fixation probability according to Eq. (53) [with Eq. (56)] becomes

ρAB\displaystyle\rho_{\!{}_{AB}} =\displaystyle= 1N+w4N2[(3N211N+8)a+(N2+3N8)b]\displaystyle\frac{1}{N}\,+\frac{w}{4N^{2}}\Big{[}\,{\left({3N^{2}-11N+8}\right)a+\left({N^{2}+3N-8}\right)b}\,\Big{]} (89)
w4N2[(N23N+8)c+(3N25N8)d]\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636pt-\frac{w}{4N^{2}}\Big{[}\,{\left({N^{2}-3N+8}\right)c+\left({3N^{2}-5N-8}\right)d}\,\Big{]}
=\displaystyle= 1N+w4[(σNa+bcσNd)σNN(abc+d)],\displaystyle\frac{1}{N}+\frac{w}{4}\Big{[}\,{\left({\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}a+b-c-\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}d}\right)-\frac{\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}}{N}\left({a-b-c+d}\right)}\,\Big{]},

where σN=38/N\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}=3-8/N. For MP, the fixation probability cannot be expressed in a closed form for general ww. However, when ww goes to zero, it can be calculated using Eq. (57), and is given by

ρAB\displaystyle\rho_{\!{}_{AB}}\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt =\displaystyle= 1N+w6N[(N2)a+(2N1)b]w6N[(N+1)c+(2N4)d]\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\frac{1}{N}+\frac{w}{6N}\Big{[}\,{(N-2)a+(2N-1)b}\,\Big{]}-\frac{w}{6N}\Big{[}\,{(N+1)c+(2N-4)d}\,\Big{]} (90)
=\displaystyle= 1N+w4[σNa+bcσNd]w4[σN3(abc+d)],\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\frac{1}{N}+\frac{w}{4}\Big{[}\,{\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}a+b-c-\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}d}\,\Big{]}-\frac{w}{4}\Big{[}\,{\frac{\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}}{3}\left({a-b-c+d}\right)}\,\Big{]},

where σN=12/N\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}=1-2/N.

The fixation probabilities for the three processes, as given by Eqs. (88-90), can be expressed as

ρAB\displaystyle\rho_{\!{}_{AB}}\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt =\displaystyle= 1N+wθa[σNa+bcσNd]wθs[σN(abc+d)],\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\frac{1}{N}+w\theta_{a}\Big{[}\,{\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}a+b-c-\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}d}\,\Big{]}-w\theta_{s}\Big{[}\,{\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}\left({a-b-c+d}\right)}\,\Big{]}, (91)

with σN\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}, θa\theta_{a}, and θs\theta_{s} given by the following table.

σNθaθsBD12N1212NDB38N1414NMP12N14112\displaystyle\begin{array}[]{||c||c|c|c||}\hline\cr\hline\cr&\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}&\mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pt\theta_{a}\mbox{}&\mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pt\theta_{s}\mbox{}\\ \hline\cr\hline\cr\mbox{BD}&1-\frac{2}{N}&\frac{1}{2}&\frac{1}{2N}\\ \hline\cr\mbox{DB}&3-\frac{8}{N}&\frac{1}{4}&\frac{1}{4N}\\ \hline\cr\mbox{MP}&1-\frac{2}{N}&\frac{1}{4}&\frac{1}{12}\\ \hline\cr\hline\cr\end{array} (96)

We would like to emphasize that the difference between ρAB\rho_{\!{}_{AB}} and ρBA\rho_{\!{}_{BA}} comes form the anti-symmetric term. In other words, strategy selection is determined by the sign of σNa+bc+σNd\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}a+b-c+\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}d. This value is identical for BD on cycle and MP. The coefficient of the anti-symmetric term, θa\theta_{a} for BD and MP would have been the same if we had normalized the accumulated payoff such that an individual in a population of mono-strategy has the same fitness both for BD and MP. For MP, each individual plays games with N1N-1 neighbors while an individual on a cycle has two neighbors. To have the same effective payoff with individual on a cycle, we need to normalize the accumulated payoff for MP by multiplying 2/(N1)2/(N-1). However, for MP, we use PrP_{r} in Eq. (1) as the average payoff which is the accumulated payoff divide by N1N-1, following the established convention (Nowak, 2006b, ). Hence, the results for MP using intensity of selection, ww should be compared with those with half of the intensity, w/2w/2 for BD and DB. We also note that the symmetric terms are of order w/Nw/N for BD and DB on cycles while it is of order ww for MP.

Fixation probability in the wNwN limit is obtained by taking NN\rightarrow\infty limit of Eq. (91) and Eq. (96);

ρAB\displaystyle\rho_{\!{}_{AB}} =\displaystyle= {1N[1+Nw2(a+bcd)]forBD1N[1+Nw4(3a+bc3d)]forDB1N[1+Nw6(a+2bc2d)]forMP.\displaystyle\left\{\begin{array}[]{ll}\frac{1}{N}\left[{1+\frac{Nw}{2}\left({a+b-c-d}\right)}\right]&\hskip-17.07164pt\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{BD}\\ \frac{1}{N}\left[{1+\frac{Nw}{4}\left({3a+b-c-3d}\right)}\right]&\hskip-17.07164pt\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{DB}\\ \frac{1}{N}\left[{1+\frac{Nw}{6}\left({a+2b-c-2d}\right)}\right]&\hskip-17.07164pt\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{MP}.\end{array}\right. (100)

These results can be understood by considering fixation process as a (biased) random walk on a one-dimensional lattice. Let TNA±T_{N_{\!A}}^{\pm} be the probability that the number of A to be NA±1{N_{\!A}}\pm 1 from NA{N_{\!A}} as introduced in Eq. (52). Then, without a mutation, we have TN=T0+=0T^{-}_{N}=T^{+}_{0}=0. Hence, there are two absorbing states, the all B state at NA=0{N_{\!A}}=0 and the all A state at NA=N{N_{\!A}}=N. Now, ρAB\rho_{\!{}_{AB}} can be interpreted as the probability that the random walker reaches the NA=N{N_{\!A}}=N state starting from the NA=1{N_{\!A}}=1 state. For large NN, the master equation describing population dynamics can be approximated by a Fokker-Plank equation with (biased) drift, vNAv_{N_{\!A}}, and the (stochastic) diffusion, dNAd_{N_{\!A}}, which are approximately given by vNA(TNA+TNA)v_{N_{\!A}}\approx(T_{N_{\!A}}^{+}-T_{N_{\!A}}^{-}) and dNA(TNA++TNA)/Nd_{N_{\!A}}\approx\left({T_{N_{\!A}}^{+}+T_{N_{\!A}}^{-}}\right)/N (Traulsen et al.,, 2006). For small ww, drift velocity is proportional to ww, and the relative contribution of the diffusion term, dNA/vNAd_{N_{\!A}}/v_{N_{\!A}} is asymptotically given by dNAvNA1Nw\frac{d_{N_{\!A}}}{v_{N_{\!A}}}\sim\frac{1}{Nw}. For weak selection (Nw1Nw\ll 1), where dNA/vNAd_{N_{\!A}}/v_{N_{\!A}} is large, the fixation probability is mainly determined by the (stochastic) diffusion term, 1/N1/N and can be written as

ρAB=1N+vAB.\displaystyle\rho_{\!{}_{AB}}=\frac{1}{N}+v_{\!{}_{AB}}. (101)

The perturbation term, vABv_{\!{}_{AB}} is the (weighted) average drift velocity over NA=1{N_{\!A}}=1 to NA=N1{N_{\!A}}=N-1 state and is given by

vAB\displaystyle v_{\!{}_{AB}} =\displaystyle= vNA=NAϕNA(TNA+TNA),\displaystyle\langle{v_{N_{\!A}}}\rangle\ =\ \sum_{N_{\!A}}\,\phi_{{}_{\!N_{\!A}}}\ (T_{N_{\!A}}^{+}-T_{N_{\!A}}^{-}), (102)

where ϕNA\phi_{{}_{\!N_{\!A}}} is the frequency of visits to the state NA{N_{\!A}} (the expected sojourn time at NA{N_{\!A}}). When ww is small, the difference between TNA+T_{N_{\!A}}^{+} and TNAT_{N_{\!A}}^{-} is also small and “walkers” can diffuse around state NA{N_{\!A}} easily. Then we can treat x=NA/Nx={N_{\!A}}/N as a continuous variable, especially when NN is large. Hence, for small ww and large NN, ϕ\phi satisfies the diffusion equation in one-dimension,

d2ϕdx\displaystyle\frac{d^{2}\phi}{dx} =\displaystyle= 0,\displaystyle 0, (103)

whose solution is given by

ϕNA\displaystyle\phi_{{}_{\!N_{\!A}}} =\displaystyle= c1+c2NAN\displaystyle c_{1}+c_{2}\,\frac{{N_{\!A}}}{N} (104)
=\displaystyle= 2N(N1)[(N1)(N2)NAN]\displaystyle\frac{2}{N(N-1)}\,\left[{(N-1)-(N-2)\frac{{N_{\!A}}}{N}}\right]
\displaystyle\approx 2N(1NAN),\displaystyle\frac{2}{N}\,\left({1-\frac{{N_{\!A}}}{N}}\right),

for NA=1,,N1{N_{\!A}}=1,\cdots,N-1. Here, two constants c1c_{1} and c2c_{2} have been determined by the boundary conditions, ϕN=1N1ϕ0\phi_{{}_{\!N}}=\frac{1}{N-1}\phi_{0} (for neutral drift of w=0w=0, ϕNϕ0=1/N11/N=1N1\frac{\phi_{{}_{\!N}}}{\phi_{0}}=\frac{1/N}{1-1/N}=\frac{1}{N-1}) and the normalization, ϕNA=1\sum\phi_{{}_{\!N_{\!A}}}=1.

Since TNA±=T±T_{N_{\!A}}^{\pm}=T^{\pm} is independent of NA{N_{\!A}} for almost every NA{N_{\!A}}, for BD (except NA=1{N_{\!A}}=1 and NA=N1{N_{\!A}}=N-1) and DB (except NA=1{N_{\!A}}=1, 2, N2N-2, and N1N-1) on cycles, vABv_{\!{}_{AB}} can be treated as a constant for large NN. By considering the motion of the domain boundary between A and B blocks, we obtain

vAB\displaystyle\hskip-17.07164ptv_{\!{}_{AB}}\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt =\displaystyle= T+T\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\langle{T^{+}-T^{-}}\rangle (107)
=\displaystyle= {w2(a+bcd)forBDw4(3a+bc3d)forDB.\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\left\{\begin{array}[]{ll}\frac{w}{2}\left({a+b-c-d}\right)&\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{BD}\\ \frac{w}{4}\left({3a+b-c-3d}\right)&\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{DB}.\end{array}\right.

For MP, TNA±T_{N_{\!A}}^{\pm} depends NA{N_{\!A}} but vABv_{\!{}_{AB}} can be also easily calculated from ϕNA\phi_{{}_{\!N_{\!A}}} of Eq. (104). During the fixation sweep, the average number of AA in the population is NA=NAϕNAN/3\langle{{N_{\!A}}}\rangle=\sum\,{N_{\!A}}\,\phi_{{}_{\!N_{\!A}}}\approx N/3. In the wNwN limit, we have

vAB\displaystyle\hskip-17.07164ptv_{\!{}_{AB}}\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt \displaystyle\approx w2NAϕNA[(ac)NA+(cd)(NNA)]\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\frac{w}{2}\sum_{N_{\!A}}\phi_{{}_{\!N_{\!A}}}\left[{(a-c)\,{N_{\!A}}+(c-d)(N-{N_{\!A}})}\right] (108)
=\displaystyle= Nw6[ac+2(bd)].\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\frac{Nw}{6}\left[{a-c+2(b-d)}\right].

Inserting vABv_{\!{}_{AB}} given by Eq. (107) or (108), into Eq. (101), we recover Eq. (100).

4.2 Strategy selection

Here, we consider the condition for the strategy SiS_{i} is more abundant than the strategy SjS_{j}, i.e., xi>xjx_{i}>x_{j}. We can write the formal expression for the condition xi>xjx_{i}>x_{j} for the general selection strength and population size using Eqs. (71) and (53). Although the formal expression may be useful to analyze abundances of strategies numerically, it provides little analytic intuition due to the complexity of the expression. Hence, here, we solve the inequalities analytically for low intensity of selection (w0w\rightarrow 0). For finite intensity of selection, we find the condition for xi>xjx_{i}>x_{j} numerically in Section 7.

When wNwN is much smaller than 1, from Eq. (91), the fixation probability, ρij\rho_{ij} is written as

ρij\displaystyle\rho_{ij} =\displaystyle= 1N[1+wdij]\displaystyle\frac{1}{N}\left[{1+wd_{ij}}\right] (109)

with

dij\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054ptd_{ij}\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt =\displaystyle= θa(σNaii+aijajiσNajj)θsσN(aiiaijaji+ajj).\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\theta_{a}\left({\,\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}a_{ii}+a_{ij}-a_{ji}-\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}a_{jj}\,}\right)-\theta_{s}\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}\left({\,a_{ii}-a_{ij}-a_{ji}+a_{jj}\,}\right). (110)

Since abundance x1x_{1} of strategy S1S_{1} is proportional to x1ux_{1}^{u} of Eq. (71), we can write,

x1\displaystyle x_{1}\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt \displaystyle\propto (1+wd12)(1+wd13)+(1+wd13)(1+wd32)+(1+wd12)(1+wd23)\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\left({1+wd_{12}}\right)\left({1+wd_{13}}\right)+\left({1+wd_{13}}\right)\left({1+wd_{32}}\right)+\left({1+wd_{12}}\right)\left({1+wd_{23}}\right) (111)
\displaystyle\approx 3+w[2(d12+d13)+d32+d23]\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt3+w\left[{2(d_{12}+d_{13})+d_{32}+d_{23}}\right]
=\displaystyle= 3+w[(d12d21)+(d13d31)]+w[(d12+d21)+(d13+d31)+(d32+d23)]\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt3\!+\!w\left[{(d_{12}\!-\!d_{21})\!+\!(d_{13}\!-\!d_{31})}\right]+w\left[{(d_{12}\!+\!d_{21})+(d_{13}\!+\!d_{31})+(d_{32}\!+\!d_{23})}\right]
=\displaystyle= 3+wj=13k=13(djk+dkj)+wk=13(d1kdk1).\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt3+w\sum_{j=1}^{3}\sum_{k=1}^{3}(d_{jk}+d_{kj})+w\sum_{k=1}^{3}(d_{1k}-d_{k1}).

In the last step, we use dii=0d_{ii}=0. In general, abundance xix_{i} of strategy SiS_{i} can be calculated similarly;

xi\displaystyle\hskip-17.07164ptx_{i} \displaystyle\propto 3+wj=13k=13(djk+dkj)+wk=13(dikdki)\displaystyle 3+w\sum_{j=1}^{3}\sum_{k=1}^{3}\left({d_{jk}+d_{kj}}\right)+w\sum_{k=1}^{3}\left({d_{ik}-d_{ki}}\right) (112)
=\displaystyle= 32wθsσNj=13k=13(ajjajkakj+akk)\displaystyle 3-2w\theta_{s}\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}\sum_{j=1}^{3}\sum_{k=1^{3}}\left({a_{jj}-a_{jk}-a_{kj}+a_{kk}}\right)
+ 2wθak=13(σNaii+aikakiσNakk).\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip 2.84526pt+\,2w\theta_{a}\sum_{k=1}^{3}\,\left({\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}a_{ii}+a_{ik}-a_{ki}-\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}a_{kk}}\right).

Since the first two terms are independent of ii, abundance order is determined by the third term. In other words, strategy SiS_{i} is more abundant than strategy SjS_{j} when

k=13lik\displaystyle\sum_{k=1}^{3}l_{ik} >\displaystyle> k=13ljk,\displaystyle\sum_{k=1}^{3}l_{jk}, (113)

where

lik\displaystyle l_{ik} =\displaystyle= σNaii+aikakiσNakk.\displaystyle\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}a_{ii}+a_{ik}-a_{ki}-\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}a_{kk}. (114)

Here, inequality (113) is derived for abundance with three strategies. Its generalization with nn strategies, k=1nlik>k=1nljk\sum_{k=1}^{n}l_{ik}>\sum_{k=1}^{n}l_{jk}, can be derived similarly.

4.3 Optional prisoner’s dilemma game

The analysis used in Section 4.2 can be also applied to strategy selection on optional prisoner’s dilemma game [with payoff given by Eq. (25)]. Let Δxu\Delta x^{u} be the difference between (unnormalized) abundance of CC and DD, i.e., Δxu=xCuxDu\Delta x^{u}=x_{\!{}_{C}}^{u}-x_{\!{}_{D}}^{u}, where xCux_{\!{}_{C}}^{u} and xDux_{\!{}_{D}}^{u} are given by Eq. (77). Then, cooperators are more abundant than defectors when Δxu\Delta x^{u} is positive. When NwNw is much less than 1, we have

Δxu\displaystyle\hskip-17.07164pt\Delta x^{u} =\displaystyle= (ρCL+ρDL)(ρCDρDC)+n(ρCLρLDρLCρDL)\displaystyle\left({\rho_{\!{}_{CL}}+\rho_{\!{}_{DL}}}\right)\left({\rho_{\!{}_{CD}}-\rho_{\!{}_{DC}}}\right)+n\left({\rho_{\!{}_{CL}}\rho_{\!{}_{LD}}-\rho_{\!{}_{LC}}\rho_{\!{}_{DL}}}\right) (115)
\displaystyle\propto 2w(dCDdDC)+nw(dCL+dLDdLCdDL)\displaystyle 2w\left({d_{CD}-d_{DC}}\right)+nw\left({d_{CL}+d_{LD}-d_{LC}-d_{DL}}\right)
=\displaystyle= 4wθa(σNR+STσNP)+2nwθa[σN(Rg)+σN(gP)]\displaystyle 4w\theta_{a}\left({\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}R+S-T-\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}P}\right)+2nw\theta_{a}\left[{\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}(R-g)+\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}(g-P)}\right]
=\displaystyle= 4wθa[2+n2σNR+ST2+n2σNR].\displaystyle 4w\theta_{a}\left[{\frac{2+n}{2}\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}R\,+\,S\,-\,T\,-\,\frac{2+n}{2}\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}R}\right].

Here θa\theta_{a} and σN\sigma_{\!{}_{N}} are given by Eq. (96) and dijd_{ij} is given by Eq. (110) with payoff matrix element given by Eq. (87). Since xC>xDx_{\!{}_{C}}>x_{\!{}_{D}} when Δxu\Delta x^{u} is positive, we have more cooperators than defectors when

σN(n)R+S\displaystyle\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}(n)\,R+S >\displaystyle> T+σN(n)P\displaystyle T+\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}(n)\,P (116)

with

σN(n)\displaystyle\hskip-17.07164pt\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}(n)\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt =\displaystyle= {(1+12n)(12N)forBD & MP(1+12n)(38N)forDB.\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\left\{\begin{array}[]{lll}\left({1+\frac{1}{2}\,n}\right)\left({1-\frac{2}{N}}\right)&\hskip-17.07164pt\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{BD\ \& MP}\\ \left({1+\frac{1}{2}\,n}\right)\left({3-\frac{8}{N}}\right)&\hskip-17.07164pt\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{DB}.\end{array}\right. (119)

For large population limit (NN\rightarrow\infty), σN(n)\sigma_{\!{}_{N}}(n) becomes

σ(n)\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\sigma(n)\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt =\displaystyle= {1+12nforBD & MP3+32nforDB.\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\left\{\begin{array}[]{lll}1+\frac{1}{2}\,n&\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{BD\ \& MP}\\ 3+\frac{3}{2}\,n&\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{DB}.\end{array}\right. (122)

The structure factor, σ(n)\sigma(n) becomes σ\sigma of Eq. (10) when n=0n=0 (without loner strategy). Then, cooperators are more abundant than defectors when R+S>T+PR+S>T+P for BD & MP and 3R+S>T+3P3R+S>T+3P for DB as expected. On the other hand, the social dilemma is completely resolved (xC>xDx_{\!{}_{C}}>x_{\!{}_{D}} whenever R>PR>P) when the number of loner types, nn, goes to infinity.

We observe that condition (116) for the success of cooperation does not depend on the loner payoff gg. This may be counter-intuitive, since the abundance of loners increases with gg, and cooperators fare better when loners increase. However, in the wNwN limit, the frequency of loners is a first-order deviation from n/(n+2)n/(n+2). The effect of this deviation on cooperators is a second-order effect that disappears in the wNwN limit.

5 Analysis of the NwNw limit

Here, we consider the results of Section 3 under the NwNw limit. We first calculate fixation probability in the large NN limit using Eq. (53). The NwNw limit is obtained by taking the w0w\to 0 limit of the result. Once we obtain fixation probability in this limit, we calculate abundance and find the condition for the strategy SiS_{i} is more abundant than the strategy SjS_{j} for three strategy games.

5.1 Fixation probability

Fixation probability of Eq. (53) is is valid for general ww and NN for BD and DB. When NN goes to infinity (with a finite ww), ρAB\rho_{\!{}_{AB}} becomes zero if y>1y>1 since the NNth power term in Eq. (53) becomes infinity. When y<1y<1, the NNth power term becomes zero and ρAB\rho_{\!{}_{AB}} of Eq. (53) becomes f/gf/g. Since y<1y<1 when a+b<c+da+b<c+d for BD (and when 3a+b<c+3d3a+b<c+3d for DB), the fixation probabilities in the limit of large population limit are given by

ρAB\displaystyle\rho_{\!{}_{AB}}\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt =\displaystyle= ew(a+b)ew(c+d)ew(a+b)ew(c+d)+ew(ab+c+d)\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\frac{e^{w(a+b)}-e^{w(c+d)}}{e^{w(a+b)}-e^{w(c+d)}+e^{w(a-b+c+d)}} (123)

when a+b>c+da+b>c+d and 0 otherwise for BD, and

ρAB\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\rho_{\!{}_{AB}}\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt =\displaystyle= [3+e2w(db)2+ew(c+d)(e2wb+e2wd)(ew(a+b)+e2wd)(e2wa+ew(c+d))2e2wb(ew(a+b)+ew(c+d))(ew(3a+b)ew(c+3d))]1\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\left[\frac{3+e^{2w(d-b)}}{2}+\frac{e^{w(c+d)}\left({e^{2wb}+e^{2wd}}\right)\left({e^{w(a+b)}+e^{2wd}}\right)\left({e^{2wa}+e^{w(c+d)}}\right)}{2e^{2wb}\left({e^{w(a+b)}+e^{w(c+d)}}\right)\left({e^{w(3a+b)}-e^{w(c+3d)}}\right)}\right]^{-1}

when 3a+b>c+3d3a+b>c+3d and 0 otherwise for DB. For MP, ρAB\rho_{\!{}_{AB}} can be approximated by Eq. (59) for large NN.

Fixation probability in the NwNw limit is obtained by taking w0w\rightarrow 0 limit to Eqs. (123) and (LABEL:e.NfixDB). In this limit, ρAB\rho_{\!{}_{AB}} becomes

ρAB\displaystyle\hskip-17.07164pt\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\rho_{\!{}_{AB}}\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt =\displaystyle= {w(a+bcd)Θ(a+bcd)forBDw(3a+bc3d)Θ(3a+bc3d)forDB.\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\left\{\begin{array}[]{ll}\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054ptw\left({\,a+b-c-\,d}\right)\Theta(\,a+b-c-\,d)&\hskip-17.07164pt\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{BD}\\ \mbox{}\hskip-5.69054ptw\left({3a+b-c-3d}\right)\Theta(3a+b-c-3d)&\hskip-17.07164pt\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{DB}.\end{array}\right. (127)

This result can be also understood from random walk argument on 1D lattice. Here, NwNw is much larger than 1 and hence diffusion to drift-velocity ratio, d/v1/Nwd/v\approx 1/Nw is small. Hence, population dynamics is mainly determined by the (biased) drift term rather than the stochastic diffusion. Fixation (random walker at NA=N{N_{\!A}}=N state) is now possible only when the drift bias is positive for (almost) everywhere. For BD and DB on cycles, drift velocity is independent of NA{N_{\!A}} and proportional to σa+bcσd\sigma a+b-c-\sigma d.

5.2 Strategy selection

We now consider the condition for xi>xjx_{i}>x_{j} in the large population limit with finite ww for BD and DB. As mentioned before, we are comparing abundance xix_{i} and xjx_{j} in the population with three strategies, SiS_{i}, SjS_{j} and SkS_{k}. We first note that xjx_{j} and xkx_{k} are zero when both ρji\rho_{ji} and ρki\rho_{ki} are zero [see Eq. (71)]. This is the case when both ljil_{ji} and lkil_{ki} are negative [see Eq. (36)] where lij=σaii+aijajiσajjl_{ij}=\sigma a_{ii}+a_{ij}-a_{ji}-\sigma a_{jj}. Therefore, 1=xi>xj=01=x_{i}>x_{j}=0 if both lijl_{ij} and likl_{ik} are positive. By the same token, 0=xi<xj=10=x_{i}<x_{j}=1 when both ljil_{ji} and ljkl_{jk} are positive. If lkil_{ki} and lkjl_{kj} are positive, both xix_{i} and xjx_{j} are zero. Hence, the condition for xi>xjx_{i}>x_{j} becomes non-trivial only when three strategies show rock-paper-scissors characteristics. For the lij>0l_{ij}>0 case (with ljk>0l_{jk}>0 and lki>0l_{ki}>0), xiux_{i}^{u} and xjux_{j}^{u} in Eq. (71) become ρijρjk\rho_{ij}\rho_{jk} and ρjkρki\rho_{jk}\rho_{ki} respectively. Therefore, SiS_{i} is more abundant than SjS_{j} when ρij>ρki\rho_{ij}>\rho_{ki}. For the other case of lji>0l_{ji}>0 (with lik>0l_{ik}>0 and lkj>0l_{kj}>0), xiux_{i}^{u} and xjux_{j}^{u} become ρikρkj\rho_{ik}\rho_{kj} and ρjiρik\rho_{ji}\rho_{ik} and xi>xjx_{i}>x_{j} when ρkj>ρji\rho_{kj}>\rho_{ji}. Hence, there are three cases that strategy SiS_{i} is more abundant than strategy SjS_{j} in the large population limit;

  • case 1  [lij>0l_{ij}>0 and lik>0l_{ik}>0]: xi>xjx_{i}>x_{j} always,

  • case 2  [lij>0l_{ij}>0, ljk>0l_{jk}>0, and lki>0l_{ki}>0]: xi>xjx_{i}>x_{j} if ρij>ρki\rho_{ij}>\rho_{ki}, and

  • case 3  [lji>0l_{ji}>0, lik>0l_{ik}>0, and lkj>0l_{kj}>0]: xi>xjx_{i}>x_{j} if ρji<ρkj\rho_{ji}<\rho_{kj}.

For the cases 2 and 3, conditions for xi>xjx_{i}>x_{j} can be understood by integrating out the role of strategy SkS_{k}. For the case 2, influx to strategy SiS_{i} is ρijxj\rho_{ij}x_{j} while out-flux is ρkixi\rho_{ki}x_{i}. Therefore, detailed balance between the abundance of SiS_{i} and SjS_{j} in the steady state requires

ρijxj\displaystyle\rho_{ij}x_{j} =\displaystyle= ρkixi.\displaystyle\rho_{ki}x_{i}. (128)

Hence, xi=ρijρkjxjx_{i}=\frac{\rho_{ij}}{\rho_{kj}}\,x_{j} is larger than xjx_{j} if ρij>ρki\rho_{ij}>\rho_{ki}. For the case 3, influx to strategy SiS_{i} is ρkjxj\rho_{kj}x_{j} when the role of strategy SkS_{k} is integrated out. Since the out-flux to strategy SiS_{i} is ρjixi\rho_{ji}x_{i}, we have

ρkjxj\displaystyle\rho_{kj}x_{j} =\displaystyle= ρjixi\displaystyle\rho_{ji}x_{i} (129)

in the steady state, and xi=ρkjρjixjx_{i}=\frac{\rho_{kj}}{\rho_{ji}}\,x_{j} is larger than xjx_{j} if ρkj>ρji\rho_{kj}>\rho_{ji}. From the large NN limit of ρij\rho_{ij} in Eq. (53), we see that the conditions for xi>xjx_{i}>x_{j} for the cases 2 and 3 become

fijgki>fkigijforcase 2fkjgji>fjigkjforcase 3.\displaystyle\begin{array}[]{llll}f_{ij}\,g_{ki}&>&f_{ki}\,g_{ij}&\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{case~2}\\ f_{kj}\,g_{ji}&>&f_{ji}\,g_{kj}&\hskip 14.22636pt\mbox{for}\ \ \mbox{case~3}.\end{array} (132)

Here

fij\displaystyle f_{ij} =\displaystyle= αiiαijαjiαjj\displaystyle\alpha_{ii}\alpha_{ij}-\alpha_{ji}\alpha_{jj}
gij\displaystyle g_{ij} =\displaystyle= αiiαijαjiαjj+αiiαij1αjiαjj\displaystyle\alpha_{ii}\alpha_{ij}-\alpha_{ji}\alpha_{jj}+\alpha_{ii}\alpha_{ij}^{-1}\alpha_{ji}\alpha_{jj} (133)

for BD, and

fij\displaystyle\hskip-17.07164pt\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054ptf_{ij}\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt =\displaystyle= αii3αijαjiαjj3\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\alpha_{ii}^{3}\alpha_{ij}-\alpha_{ji}\alpha_{jj}^{3}
gij\displaystyle\hskip-17.07164pt\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054ptg_{ij}\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt =\displaystyle= 3fij+αij1αjj2fij2+αjiαjj(αij2+αjj2)(αiiαij+αjj2)(αii2+αjiαjj)2αij2(αiiαij+αjiαjj)\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\frac{3f_{ij}+\alpha_{ij}^{-1}\alpha_{jj}^{2}f_{ij}}{2}\!+\!\frac{\alpha_{ji}\alpha_{jj}\left({\alpha_{ij}^{2}+\alpha_{jj}^{2}}\right)\left({\alpha_{ii}\alpha_{ij}+\alpha_{jj}^{2}}\right)\left({\alpha_{ii}^{2}+\alpha_{ji}\alpha_{jj}}\right)}{2\alpha_{ij}^{2}\left({\alpha_{ii}\alpha_{ij}+\alpha_{ji}\alpha_{jj}}\right)} (134)

for DB with αij=ewaij\alpha_{ij}=e^{wa_{ij}}.

Now we consider the NwNw limit, where ww goes to zero after NN goes to infinity. In this case, fijf_{ij} and gijg_{ij} in Eq. (134) become linear in ww and ρij\rho_{ij} becomes proportional to lijl_{ij} (unless lij<0l_{ij}<0 where ρij=0\rho_{ij}=0). The conditions for three cases for large population become

  • case 1  [lij>0l_{ij}>0 and lik>0l_{ik}>0]: xi>xjx_{i}>x_{j} always.

  • case 2  [lij>0l_{ij}>0, ljk>0l_{jk}>0, and lki>0l_{ki}>0]: xi>xjx_{i}>x_{j} if lij>lkil_{ij}>l_{ki}.

  • case 3  [lji>0l_{ji}>0, lik>0l_{ik}>0, and lkj>0l_{kj}>0]: xi>xjx_{i}>x_{j} if lji<lkjl_{ji}<l_{kj}.

5.3 Optional prisoner’s dilemma game

We now consider optional prisoner’s dilemma game whose payoff matrix is given by Eq. (25). We first assume R>PR>P. In general, the effect of loners on the strategy selection between C and D disappears if R=PR=P due to the symmetry. Hence, we need to consider RPR\not=P case only and assume R>PR>P without loss of generality. We further assume that R>gR>g. Otherwise, both lCL=σ(Rg)l_{CL}=\sigma(R-g) and lDL=σ(Pg)l_{DL}=\sigma(P-g) are negative and both xCx_{\!{}_{C}} and xDx_{\!{}_{D}} become 0. When we assume R>PR>P and R>gR>g, two possibilities are left, P>gP>g and P<gP<g.

As before, we consider the difference between xCux_{\!{}_{C}}^{u} and xDux_{\!{}_{D}}^{u} [given by Eq. (77)] and let Δxu=xCuxDu\Delta x^{u}=x_{\!{}_{C}}^{u}-x_{\!{}_{D}}^{u}. When g<Pg<P, both ρLC\rho_{\!{}_{LC}} and ρLD\rho_{\!{}_{LD}} are zero since both lLCl_{LC} and lLDl_{LD} are negative and we get

Δxu\displaystyle\Delta x^{u} =\displaystyle= (ρCL+ρDL)(ρCDρDC)\displaystyle\left({\rho_{\!{}_{CL}}+\rho_{\!{}_{DL}}}\right)\left({\rho_{\!{}_{CD}}-\rho_{\!{}_{DC}}}\right) (135)

from Eq. (77). Therefore, xC>xDx_{\!{}_{C}}>x_{\!{}_{D}} when

ρCD\displaystyle\rho_{\!{}_{CD}} >\displaystyle> ρDC.\displaystyle\rho_{\!{}_{DC}}. (136)

This can be easily understood since abundance of loners becomes zero when Nw1Nw\gg 1 in the g<Pg<P case. On the other hands, for the g>Pg>P case, Δxu\Delta x^{u} becomes

Δxu\displaystyle\Delta x^{u} =\displaystyle= ρCL(ρCD+nρLDρDC).\displaystyle\rho_{\!{}_{CL}}\left({\rho_{\!{}_{CD}}+n\rho_{\!{}_{LD}}-\rho_{\!{}_{DC}}}\right). (137)

Therefore, xC>xDx_{\!{}_{C}}>x_{\!{}_{D}} when

ρCD\displaystyle\rho_{\!{}_{CD}} >\displaystyle> ρDCnρLD.\displaystyle\rho_{\!{}_{DC}}-n\rho_{\!{}_{LD}}. (138)

The inequalities (136) and (138) are valid as long as NwNw is much larger than 1 for general ww. There are three possibilities for NwNw to go infinity, ww goes to infinity, NN goes to infinity or both go to infinity. Let us first consider the NwNw limit in which NN\to\infty first and then w0w\to 0. In this case, the conditions for xC>xDx_{\!{}_{C}}>x_{\!{}_{D}} on cycles, inequalities (136) and (138) can be written as linear inequalities. Here, ρCDρDC\rho_{\!{}_{CD}}-\rho_{\!{}_{DC}} is always proportional to lCDl_{CD}. Also, ρLD\rho_{\!{}_{LD}} becomes proportional to lLDl_{LD} if g>Pg>P. Therefore, we have xC>xDx_{\!{}_{C}}>x_{\!{}_{D}} when

σR+S\displaystyle\hskip-17.07164pt\sigma R+S >\displaystyle\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt>\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt T+σPnσ(gP)Θ(gP),\displaystyle T+\sigma P-n\sigma(g-P)\Theta(g-P), (139)

where σ=1\sigma=1 for BD and 3 for DB.

Now, let us consider high intensity of selection limit where ww itself goes to infinity. Then, ρLD\rho_{\!{}_{LD}} becomes 1 when g>Pg>P since loners dominates defectors and inequality (138) becomes

ρCD\displaystyle\rho_{\!{}_{CD}} >\displaystyle> ρDCn.\displaystyle\rho_{\!{}_{DC}}-n. (140)

This implies that cooperators are more abundant than defectors always for large ww if n>1n>1 since ρDC\rho_{\!{}_{DC}} cannot be larger than 1.

6 Optional game with simplified prisoner’s dilemma

To further clarify how spatial structure and optionality of the game affect the success of cooperation, we study a optional version of a simplified prisonser’s dilemma, in which cooperators pay a cost cc to generate a benefit bb for the other player. This simplified prisoner’s dilemma is also known as the donation game or the prisoner’s dilemma with equal gains from switching. Here, we consider the n=1n=1 optional game with a simplified prisoner’s dilemma, whose payoff matrix is given by

CDLCDL(bccgb0gggg).\displaystyle\begin{array}[]{cl}&\begin{array}[]{ccc}\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636ptC&\mbox{}\hskip 28.45274pt\ \ D&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636ptL\end{array}\\ \begin{array}[]{c}C\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\\ D\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\\ L\mbox{}\hskip-5.69054pt\end{array}&\left(\begin{array}[]{ccc}b-c&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636pt-c&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636pt\ g\\ b&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636pt0&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636pt\ g\\ g&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636ptg&\mbox{}\hskip 14.22636pt\ g\end{array}\right).\end{array} (150)

Here, gg is the payoff for a loner (for staying away from a game) and bb and cc are the benefit and cost of the cooperation respectively. We assume that the cost to participate the game, gg, is positive but less than the benefit of cooperation and consider parameter regions of 0<c<b0<c<b and 0<g<b0<g<b.

For the simplified PD game, we have R=bcR=b-c, S=cS=-c, T=bT=b and P=0P=0 and the condition for xC>xDx_{\!{}_{C}}>x_{\!{}_{D}} in the wNwN limit, given by inequality (116), becomes

c\displaystyle c <\displaystyle< N65N6b=b5+O(1/N)\displaystyle\frac{N-6}{5N-6}\,b\ =\ \frac{b}{5}+O(1/N) (151)

for BD and MP, and

c\displaystyle c <\displaystyle< 7N2411N24b=7b11+O(1/N)\displaystyle\frac{7N-24}{11N-24}\,b\ =\ \frac{7b}{11}+O(1/N) (152)

for DB. Note that the condition for xC>xDx_{\!{}_{C}}>x_{\!{}_{D}} is independent of gg, as we saw earlier in Section 4.3. In the wNwN limit, the condition for xC>xDx_{\!{}_{C}}>x_{\!{}_{D}} mainly depends on the frequency of loners, which is roughly 1/3 regardless of gg values.

On the other hand, in the NwNw limit, inequality (139) becomes

g\displaystyle g >\displaystyle> 2c\displaystyle 2c (153)

for BD and

g\displaystyle g >\displaystyle> 43(cb/2)\displaystyle\frac{4}{3}\left({c-b/2}\right) (154)

for DB.

Now we consider the large ww limit (w1w\gg 1). First, note that the condition for xC>xDx_{\!{}_{C}}>x_{\!{}_{D}}, given by inequality (138), becomes

ρCD\displaystyle\rho_{\!{}_{CD}} >\displaystyle> ρDCρLD\displaystyle\rho_{\!{}_{DC}}-\rho_{\!{}_{LD}} (155)

when n=1n=1. The fixation probabilities, ρCD\rho_{\!{}_{CD}}, ρDC\rho_{\!{}_{DC}} and ρLD\rho_{\!{}_{LD}} can be easily calculated from Eq. (53) for large ww. For BD, ρCD\rho_{\!{}_{CD}}, ρDC\rho_{\!{}_{DC}} and ρLD\rho_{\!{}_{LD}} become ecNwe^{-cNw}, 1e(b+2c)w1-e^{-(b+2c)w} and 1egw1-e^{-gw} respectively for sufficiently large ww and inequality (155) becomes

ecNw\displaystyle e^{-cNw} >\displaystyle> egwe(b+2c)w.\displaystyle e^{-gw}-e^{-(b+2c)w}. (156)

Since, egwe^{-gw} is larger than e(b+2c)we^{-(b+2c)w} when g<bg<b, inequality (155) cannot be satisfied for large population (N>g/cN>g/c). In other words, xDx_{\!{}_{D}} is always larger than xCx_{\!{}_{C}} for BD in the ww\rightarrow\infty limit. It is worthwhile to note how strongly strategy selection depends on the number of loner types for large ww. As discussed before, cooperators are more abundant than defectors if the types of loners, nn is larger than 1. On the other hand, for n=1n=1, defectors are more abundant than cooperators as long as 0<g<b0<g<b.

For DB, we get similar results for ρCD\rho_{\!{}_{CD}} and ρLD\rho_{\!{}_{LD}}. As ww goes to infinity, ρCD\rho_{\!{}_{CD}} becomes zero while ρLD\rho_{\!{}_{LD}} becomes 2/32/3. On the other hand, ρDC\rho_{\!{}_{DC}} depends on the benefit to cost ratio. It is 2/32/3 if cc is larger than b/2b/2 and zero otherwise. Hence, cooperators are more abundant than defectors when c<b/2c<b/2.

For MP, we calculate fixation probabilities directly using Eq. (52) in the limit of ww\rightarrow\infty and find that ρCD/ρDC\rho_{\!{}_{CD}}/\rho_{\!{}_{DC}} becomes 1+ewcewg1+e^{-wc}-e^{-wg} for large ww. Hence, cooperators are more abundant than defectors when g>cg>c.

This simplified game allows us to examine how spatial structure and optionality of the game combine to support cooperation.

7 Numerical analysis

We have analyzed the conditions for strategy selection analytically in the two extreme limits of selection intensity, w0w\to 0 and ww\to\infty in the zero mutation rate. Here, we first we obtain conditions for xC>xDx_{\!{}_{C}}>x_{\!{}_{D}} in the simplified game (150) numerically for finite values of ww (with low mutation rate), using calculated abundance from fixation probabilities. Then, we perform a series of Monte Carlo simulations with small but finite mutation rates. The condition for strategy selection is obtained numerically using measured abundance in the simulations.

7.1 Numerical comparison of abundance of cooperators and defectors

Refer to caption
Figure 1: C-rich (blue-vertical) and D-rich (red-horizontal) regions for BD in the cc-gg parameter space. Population size is N=104N=10^{4} and selection intensities are (a) w=106w=10^{-6}, (b) w=102w=10^{-2}, (c) w=1w=1, and (d) w=10w=10. Black lines in (a), and (b) are given by c=1/5c=1/5 and g=2cg=2c respectively.
Refer to caption
Figure 2: C-rich (blue-vertical) and D-rich (red-horizontal) regions for DB in the cc-gg parameter space. Population size is N=104N=10^{4} and selection intensities are (a) w=106w=10^{-6}, (b) w=102w=10^{-2}, (c) w=1w=1, and (d) w=10w=10. Black lines in (a), (b), and (d) are given by c=7/11c=7/11 g=43(c12)g=\frac{4}{3}\left({c-\frac{1}{2}}\right), and c=1/2c=1/2 respectively.
Refer to caption
Figure 3: C-rich (blue-vertical) and D-rich (red-horizontal) regions for MP in the cc-gg parameter space. Population size is N=100N=100 and selection intensities are (a) w=103w=10^{-3}, (b) w=101w=10^{-1}, (c) w=1w=1, and (d) w=10w=10. Black lines in (a) and (d) are given by c=1/5c=1/5 and g=cg=c respectively.

We solve the inequality xC>xDx_{\!{}_{C}}>x_{\!{}_{D}} numerically using abundance given by Eq. (77) with n=1n=1 and investigate how the boundaries between C-rich and D-rich regions in the parameter space change as the selection intensity, ww varies. Without loss of generality, we set b=1b=1 and investigate the parameter space given by 0<c<10<c<1 and 0<g<10<g<1. The boundaries are obtained by finding cc which satisfies xC=xDx_{\!{}_{C}}=x_{\!{}_{D}} for a given gg.

In Fig. 1, we draw C-rich and D-rich regions for BD by blue-vertical and red-horizontal lines respectively for four different values of selection intensities. C-rich regions in (a) and (b) are consistent with the analysis in the wNwN limit [inequality (151)] and in the NwNw limit [inequality (153)] respectively. The dark-dashed lines, given by c=1/5c=1/5 and g=2cg=2c, are the boundaries between C-rich and D-rich regions predicted in the wNwN and NwNw limits respectively. For w=10w=10 shown in (d), defectors are more abundant for almost entire region. This is consistent with the ww\rightarrow\infty analysis which always predict xD>xCx_{\!{}_{D}}>x_{\!{}_{C}} for n=1n=1. For the intermediate value of w=1w=1 shown in (c), we do not know the analytic boundary but we observe that the numerical boundary lies between the boundary for w=102w=10^{-2} of (b) and that for w=10w=10 of (d) as expected.

For DB, we show C-rich and D-rich regions for N=104N=10^{4} in Fig. 2. As in Fig. 1, they are represented by blue-vertical and red-horizontal lines respectively for four different values of selection intensities. C-rich regions in (a) and (b) coincide with the predictions for the wNwN and NwNw limits respectively. The dark-dashed lines, given by c=7/11c=7/11 and g=43(c12)g=\frac{4}{3}\left({c-\frac{1}{2}}\right), are the boundaries between C-rich and D-rich regions predicted in the wNwN and NwNw limits respectively. For w=10w=10 shown in (d), cooperators are more abundant if c<1/2c<1/2 as predicted in the ww\rightarrow\infty limit. As in the case of BD, we do not know the analytic boundary for the intermediate value of w=1w=1 shown in (c). Yet, at least, we confirm that the numerical boundary lies between the boundary in the NwNw limit and that in the ww\rightarrow\infty limit.

In Fig. 3, we show C-rich and D-rich regions for MP by blue-vertical and red-horizontal lines respectively. For MP, we do not have an analytic expression for the fixation probability in a closed form. Hence we need to calculate fixation probabilities directly from Eq. (52). Due to numerical cost for calculating abundance, which increases rapidly with NN, we investigate relatively small population of N=100N=100. However, they seem to be big enough to confirm the analytic prediction of the boundaries between C-rich and D-rich regions in the wNwN limit and in the large ww limit. The dark-dashed lines in (a) and (d), given by c=1/5c=1/5 and g=cg=c, are the predicted boundaries in the wNwN and large ww limits respectively.

7.2 Combined effects of optionality and spatial structure

Now, let us compare the effects of the option to be loners on the structured population (BD and DB) to those on the well-mixed population (MP). It is immediately clear that the effects of spatial structure depend on the update rule. Comparing Figures 1 and 3, we see that BD updating does not support cooperation, in accordance with findings from other models (Ohtsuki & Nowak,, 2006; Ohtsuki et al.,, 2006; Hauert et al.,, 2014) In panels 1(a) and 3(a), where Nw=0.1Nw=0.1, the C-rich regions for BD and MP appear to coincide. This accords with our results that, in the wNwN limit, the condition for xC>xDx_{C}>x_{D} is c<b/5c<b/5 for both MP and BD (see Section 6). In the other panels of Figures 1 and 3, we see that the C-rich regions for BD are smaller than those for MP, suggesting that BD updating actually impedes cooperation relative to its success in a well-mixed population.

DB updating is generally favorable to cooperation, as can be seen by comparing Figures 2 and 3. In the wNwN limit, for example, the condition for xC>xDx_{C}>x_{D} is c<7b/11c<7b/11 under DB updating (see Section 6), which is less stringent than the corresponding condition for MP, c<b/5c<b/5. These conditions correspond approximately to the C-rich regions shown in Figrues 2(a) and 3(a). However, we find that as ww increases, the C-rich regions for DB do not necessarily contain those for MP. In other words, for large selection intensity, there are parameter combinations under which cooperation is favored in a well-mixed population but disfavored on the cycle with DB updating. This effect is most visible in Figures 2(d) and 3(d), but it can also be seen in 2(c) and 3(c). In the ww\to\infty limit, we found (Section 6) that cooperation is favored for MP if c<gc<g, while it is favored for DB for c<b/2c<b/2. Either one of these conditions can be satisfied while the other fails, as can be seen (approximately) in Figures 2(d) and 3(d).

Optionality of the game and spatial structure (with DB updating) are two mechanisms that support cooperation. Do these mechanisms combine in a synergistic way? We find little evidence that they do. Let us consider first the wNwN limit. With spatial structure alone (DB updating with n=0n=0 loner strategies), cooperation succeeds if c<b/2c<b/2. With optionality alone (MP with n=1n=1), cooperation succeeds if c<b/5c<b/5. With both optionality and spatial structure (DB with n=1n=1), the condition is c<7b/11c<7b/11, and we observe that the 7b/117b/11 threshold is less than the sum b/2+b/5=7b/10b/2+b/5=7b/10 of the thesholds corresponding to the the two mechanisms acting alone. The lack of synergy is even more apparent as the selection intensity ww increases, since, as noted above, there are parameter combinations for which cooperation is favored for MP but disfavored for DB.

7.3 Effects of selection intensity

Refer to caption
Figure 4: Selection intensity, ww, dependence of abundance, xx, of cooperators (blue) and defectors (red) for BD [(a) and (b)], DB [(c) and (d)], and MP [(e) and (f)]. Abundance is numerically calculated using Eq. (71) with N=104N=10^{4} for BD and DB, and N=100N=100 for MP. The benefit of cooperation, bb, is 1. The costs for a game and a cooperative play, denoted by gg and cc respectively, are shown in the figures. Selection intensity ww [xx-axis] is shown in a log scale while abundance xx [yy-axis] is shown in a linear scale. Abundance of loners (not shown) is given by xL=1xCxDx_{\!{}_{L}}=1-x_{\!{}_{C}}-x_{\!{}_{D}}.
Refer to caption
Figure 5: Abundance xCx_{\!{}_{C}}, xDx_{\!{}_{D}}, and xLx_{\!{}_{L}} vs. cc for BD with N=50N=50 and w=0.002w=0.002 for four different values of gg, (a) 0, (b) 0.2, (c) 0.4, and (d) 0.6. Blue plus, red cross, and green square symbols represent the xCx_{\!{}_{C}}, xDx_{\!{}_{D}}, and xLx_{\!{}_{L}} respectively. Blue, red, and green solid lines are abundance of Eq. (71). Mutation rate is u=0.0002u=0.0002.
Refer to caption
Figure 6: Abundance xCx_{\!{}_{C}}, xDx_{\!{}_{D}}, and xLx_{\!{}_{L}} vs. cc for DB with N=50N=50 and w=0.002w=0.002 for four different values of gg, (a) 0, (b) 0.2, (c) 0.4, and (d) 0.6. Blue plus, red cross, and green square symbols represent the xCx_{\!{}_{C}}, xDx_{\!{}_{D}}, and xLx_{\!{}_{L}} respectively. Blue, red, and green solid lines are abundance of Eq. (71). Mutation rate is u=0.0002u=0.0002.

Let us now take a closer look at the effects of selection intensity. As shown in Fig. 1-3, the boundary between CC-rich region and DD-rich region changes as the selection intensity, ww varies. In other words, selection intensity may switch the rank of strategy abundance for some regions of parameter space as recently reported (Wu et al.,, 2013). In Fig. 4, we show selection intensity dependence of abundance for a couple of different pairs of cc and gg. Abundance is numerically calculated using Eq. (71) with N=104N=10^{4} for BD and DB. For MP, we consider N=100N=100 due to numerical cost. In the left panels, we choose parameters cc and gg such that cooperators are more abundant than defectors (xC>xDx_{\!{}_{C}}>x_{\!{}_{D}}) in the wNwN limit but change abundance order (xD>xCx_{\!{}_{D}}>x_{\!{}_{C}}) in the NwNw limit (for BD and DB) or large ww limit (for MP). For (a) BD, (c) DB, and (e) MP, we choose (c,g)=(0.1,0.1)(c,g)=(0.1,0.1), (0.55,0.1)(0.55,0.1), and (0.1,0.1)(0.1,0.1) respectively and find “crossing intensity”, wcw_{c}. Population remains as CC-rich phase for w<wcw<w_{c} where wcw_{c} is around 0.0005, 0.4, and 0.08 for (a), (c), and (e) respectively. In the right panels, we consider the opposite cases and choose parameters such that defectors are more abundant in the wNwN limit but becomes less abundant in the NwNw limit (for BD and DB) or large ww limit (for MP). For (b) BD, (d) DB, and (f) MP, we choose (c,g)=(0.25,0.6)(c,g)=(0.25,0.6), (0.655,0.215)(0.655,0.215), and (0.3,0.5)(0.3,0.5) respectively. For BD and DB, cooperators seem to be more abundant only in the NwNw limit. They are less abundant than defectors for large ww limit as well as in the wNwN limit. In other words, there are two crossing intensities, wc1w_{c_{1}} and wc2w_{c_{2}}, such that xCx_{\!{}_{C}} is larger than xDx_{\!{}_{D}} only for wc1<w<wc2w_{c_{1}}<w<w_{c_{2}}. They are given by wc1=0.0003w_{c_{1}}=0.0003 and wc2=0.25w_{c_{2}}=0.25 for (b) and wc1=0.001w_{c_{1}}=0.001 and wc2=0.04w_{c_{2}}=0.04 for (d). For MP shown in (f), there seems to be only one crossing point around at w=0.1w=0.1.

Refer to caption
Figure 7: Abundance xCx_{\!{}_{C}}, xDx_{\!{}_{D}}, and xLx_{\!{}_{L}} vs. cc for MP with N=50N=50 and w=0.002w=0.002 for four different values of gg, (a) 0, (b) 0.2, (c) 0.4, and (d) 0.6. Blue plus, red cross, and green square symbols represent the xCx_{\!{}_{C}}, xDx_{\!{}_{D}}, and xLx_{\!{}_{L}} respectively. Blue, red, and green solid lines are abundance of Eq. (71). Mutation rate is u=0.0002u=0.0002.

7.4 Simulation with finite mutation rate

Abundance of Eq. (71) is calculated in the low mutation limit using the fixation probabilities. After the invasion of a mutant to the mono-strategy population, the possibility of further mutation during the fixation is ignored. Strictly speaking, this is valid only when the mutation rate uu goes to zero. Here, we measure the abundance of three strategies, xCx_{\!{}_{C}}, xDx_{\!{}_{D}}, and xLx_{\!{}_{L}} by Monte Carlo simulations with a small but finite mutation rate and compare them with abundance of Eq. (71).

We start from a random arrangement of three strategies CC, DD, and LL on a cycle (BD and DB) or a complete graph (MP) with NN sites. Population evolves with BD, DB, or MP updating. The mutation probability of the offspring is uu; it bears its parent strategy with probability 1u1-u and takes one of the other two strategies with probability uu. In the mutation process, both strategies have equal chances, i.e., probability of u/2u/2 for each.

Refer to caption
Figure 8: Abundance xCx_{\!{}_{C}}, xDx_{\!{}_{D}}, and xLx_{\!{}_{L}} vs. cc for BD with N=50N=50 and w=0.2w=0.2 for four different values of gg, (a) 0, (b) 0.2, (c) 0.4, and (d) 0.6. Blue plus, red cross, and green square symbols represent the xCx_{\!{}_{C}}, xDx_{\!{}_{D}}, and xLx_{\!{}_{L}} respectively. Blue, red, and green solid lines are abundance of Eq. (71). Mutation rate is u=0.0002u=0.0002.
Refer to caption
Figure 9: Abundance xCx_{\!{}_{C}}, xDx_{\!{}_{D}}, and xLx_{\!{}_{L}} vs. cc for DB with N=50N=50 and w=0.2w=0.2 for four different values of gg, (a) 0, (b) 0.2, (c) 0.4, and (d) 0.6. Blue plus, red cross, and green square symbols represent the xCx_{\!{}_{C}}, xDx_{\!{}_{D}}, and xLx_{\!{}_{L}} respectively. Blue, red, and green solid lines are abundance of Eq. (71). Mutation rate is u=0.0002u=0.0002.

To get statistical properties, we perform M=6×104M=6\times 10^{4} independent simulations and calculate the average frequencies of strategies. We monitor the time evolution of the average frequencies and see if the population evolves to a steady state in which average frequency remains constant. In the ensemble of steady states, we believe that the probability distribution of frequencies are stationary. For a single simulation, frequencies in the population may oscillate through mutation-fixation cycles for small mutation rates. However, the ensemble average of MM independent simulations effectively provides mean frequencies equivalent to time average over many fixations. We call this mean frequency as abundance.

Refer to caption
Figure 10: Abundance xCx_{\!{}_{C}}, xDx_{\!{}_{D}}, and xLx_{\!{}_{L}} vs. cc for MP with N=50N=50 and w=0.2w=0.2 for four different values of gg, (a) 0, (b) 0.2, (c) 0.4, and (d) 0.6. Blue plus, red cross, and green square symbols represent the xCx_{\!{}_{C}}, xDx_{\!{}_{D}}, and xLx_{\!{}_{L}} respectively. Blue, red, and green solid lines are abundance of Eq. (71). Mutation rate is u=0.0002u=0.0002.

Time to reach a steady state from the random initial configuration increases rapidly with population size NN. Hence, we simulate relatively small population of N=50N=50. We use mutation rate u=0.0002u=0.0002 such that Nu=0.01Nu=0.01 in all simulations.

We first measure abundance of cooperators, xCx_{\!{}_{C}}, defectors, xDx_{\!{}_{D}}, and loners, xLx_{\!{}_{L}} in the small NwNw regime with Nw=0.1Nw=0.1. Abundance versus cost, xx-cc plots are shown in Fig. 56, and 7 for BD, DB, and MP respectively. For each updating process, we simulate population dynamics with 21 different values of cc, c=0.c=0., 0.05, \ldots ,  1, for each of four different values of gg, (a) 0, (b) 0.2, (c) 0.4, and (d) 0.6. Blue plus, red cross, and green square symbols represent the xCx_{\!{}_{C}}, xDx_{\!{}_{D}}, and xLx_{\!{}_{L}} respectively. They are compared with abundance of Eq. (71), calculated using fixation probabilities, which are represented by blue, red, and green solid lines. We first note that the abundance of all strategies are around 1/3 as expected in the wNwN limit. Measured data from simulations are consistent with abundance of Eq. (71) except a tiny but systematic deviation. When abundance is larger than 1/3, measured data tend to stay below the lines while they seem to stay above the lines when it is smaller than 1/3. These deviations seem to come from the fact that we use finite mutation rate (u=0.0002u=0.0002) instead of infinitesimal rate. Random mutations make abundance move to the average value (1/3) regardless of its strategy. Except this small discrepancy, simulation data seem to follow all features of calculated abundance of Eq. (71). For example, xDx_{\!{}_{D}} and xLx_{\!{}_{L}} increase linearly and xCx_{\!{}_{C}} decreases linearly with increasing cc. Especially, we note that crossing points of xCx_{\!{}_{C}} and xDx_{\!{}_{D}} are independent of gg as predicted. xCx_{\!{}_{C}} and xDx_{\!{}_{D}} meet near c=1/5c=1/5 for BD and MP, and near c=7/110.64c=7/11\simeq 0.64 for DB.

Refer to caption
Refer to caption
Refer to caption
Figure 11: Normalized abundance difference between cooperators and defectors, r=(xCxD)/(xC+xD)r=(x_{\!{}_{C}}-x_{\!{}_{D}})/(x_{\!{}_{C}}+x_{\!{}_{D}}) in the small NwNw regime with N=50N=50 and w=0.002w=0.002 (Nw=0.1Nw=0.1), for (a) BD, (b) DB, and (c) MP. Mutation rate is u=0.0002u=0.0002. The vertical blue and the horizontal red paintings represent C-rich and D-rich regions respectively. The dashed line is the boundary for xC=xDx_{\!{}_{C}}=x_{\!{}_{D}} in the low mutation limit of u0u\rightarrow 0.

Simulation data for the large NwNw also follow the predicted abundance of Eq. (71) quite well. Figures 8, 9 and and 10 show xx-cc plots for BD, DB, and MP respectively for w=0.2w=0.2 (Nw=10Nw=10). As before, xCx_{\!{}_{C}}, xDx_{\!{}_{D}}, and xLx_{\!{}_{L}} versus cc graphs are represented by blue plus, red cross, and green square symbols respectively for four different values of gg, (a) 0, (b) 0.2, (c) 0.4, and (d) 0.6. They are compared with calculated abundance of Eq. (71), shown by blue, red, and green solid lines. As before, we observe small but systematic discrepancies between simulation data and predicted abundance of Eq. (71). Measure abundance deference between (different) strategies are smaller than the predictions. This can be understood from the fact that mutations reduce the abundance difference between strategies. Aside from this systematic deviation, simulation data follow the features of predicted abundance very well.

We now investigate C-rich and D-rich regions in the parameter space of cc and gg and compare them with those in the low mutation limit. We first measure xCx_{\!{}_{C}} and xDx_{\!{}_{D}} for 21×2121\times 21 different cc-gg pairs in r[0 1]r\in[0\ 1] and g[0 1]g\in[0\ 1] with intervals of 0.05. Then, we plot a normalized abundance difference between cooperators and defectors, r=(xCxD)/(xC+xD)r=(x_{\!{}_{C}}-x_{\!{}_{D}})/(x_{\!{}_{C}}+x_{\!{}_{D}}) in color in 21×2121\times 21 mesh in the cc-gg parameter space (Figs. 11 and 12) to illustrate C-rich and D-rich regions. As before, we use population of N=50N=50 with mutation rate u=0.0002u=0.0002. The blue-vertical and the red-horizontal paintings represent C-rich and D-rich regions respectively.

Refer to caption
Refer to caption
Refer to caption
Figure 12: Normalized abundance difference between cooperators and defectors, r=(xCxD)/(xC+xD)r=(x_{\!{}_{C}}-x_{\!{}_{D}})/(x_{\!{}_{C}}+x_{\!{}_{D}}) in the large NwNw regime with N=50N=50 and w=0.2w=0.2 (Nw=10Nw=10), for (a) BD, (b) DB, and (c) MP. Mutation rate is u=0.0002u=0.0002. The vertical blue and the horizontal red paintings represent C-rich and D-rich regions respectively. The dashed line is the boundary for xC=xDx_{\!{}_{C}}=x_{\!{}_{D}} in the low mutation limit.

Figure 11 shows the normalized abundance difference, rr in the small NwNw regime for the three processes with w=0.002w=0.002 (Nw=0.1Nw=0.1). As predicted by the panels (a) in Fig. 1-3, blue-rich region changes to red-rich region as cc increases, more or less, uniformly regardless of gg values. The phase boundaries calculated in the low mutation limit are shown in black-dashed lines. Those lines locate near c=1/5c=1/5 for BD and MP and near c=7/11c=7/11 for DB updating and they are consistent to the boundaries between two colors.

Boundaries (of C-rich and D-rich regions) obtained from the simulations for the large NwNw regime are also consistent with those calculated in the low mutation limit. Figure 12 shows the normalized abundance difference, rr in color for the three processes with w=0.2w=0.2 (Nw=10Nw=10) in the cc-gg parameter space. As in Fig. 11, the blue-vertical and the red-horizontal paintings represent C-rich and D-rich regions respectively. The phase boundaries calculated in the low mutation limit are shown in black-dashed lines. They are consistent with color boundaries quite well expect for large gg for BD updating. We observe that cooperators favored over defectors for wider range of cc for large gg for BD updating. However, the absolute abundance of cooperators is small (although it is still larger than xDx_{\!{}_{D}}) when gg is large, since loners prevail the population.

8 Conclusion

We have analyzed strategy selection in optional games on cycles and on complete graphs and found a non-trivial interaction between volunteering and spatial selection.

For 2×22\times 2 games on cycles using exponential fitness, we have presented a closed form expression for the fixation probability for any intensity of selection and any population size. Using this fixation probability, we have found the conditions for strategy selection analytically in the limits of weak intensity of selection and large population size. We have presented results for two orders of limits: (i) w0w\to 0 followed by NN\to\infty (which we call the wNwN-limit) and (ii) NN\to\infty followed by w0w\to 0 (which we call the NwNw-limit). In the first case we have wN1wN\ll 1; in the second we have Nw1Nw\gg 1. We have also obtained numerical results for finite ww in the low mutation limit.

According to our observations, increasing the number of loner strategies relaxes the social dilemma and promotes evolution of cooperation. Increasing the number of loner strategies is equivalent to increasing mutational bias toward loner strategies. More loner strategies (or equivalently, more bias in mutation toward loners) favors cooperation by enabling loners to invade defector clusters and facilitate the return of cooperators. In the limit of an infinite number of loner strategies the social dilemma is completely resolved for any selection intensity. For high intensity of selection (w1w\gg 1), the social dilemma can be fully resolved if there is mutational bias toward loner strategies (or there are more than one loner strategies).

While optionality of the game and spatial population structure both support cooperation, we have not found evidence of synergy between these mechanisms. This lack of synergy appears due to the fact that these mechanisms act in different ways. Spatial structure supports cooperation by allowing cooperators to isolate themselves, while optionality supports cooperation by allowing loners to infiltrate defectors. Neither mechanism appears to improve the efficacy of the other. In fact, for strong selection (the ww\to\infty limit) these mechanisms appear to counteract one another, in that there are parameter combinations for which coopeation is favored in the well-mixed population but disfavored for DB updating on the cycle.

We speculate that the role of loner strategies in relaxing social dilemmas, which we observe in our study, is qualitatively valid for games on general graphs. Since the population structures in our study, cycles and complete graphs, are at the two extreme ends of the spectrum of spatial structures, we expect loner strategies in optional games on other graphs also to relax social dilemma. The relaxation effect of volunteering increases as more loner strategies are available.

9 Acknowledgments

Support from the program for Foundational Questions in Evolutionary Biology (FQEB), the National Philanthropic Trust, the John Templeton Foundation and the National Research Foundation of Korea grant (NRF-2010-0022474) is gratefully acknowledged.

References

  • Allen et al., (2013) Allen, B., Gore, J., Nowak, M. A. & Bergstrom, C. T. 2013. Spatial dilemmas of diffusible public goods. eLife, 2, e01169.
  • Allen & Nowak, (2014) Allen, B. & Nowak, M. 2014. Games on graphs. EMS Surv. Math. Sci. 1 (1), 113–151.
  • Batali & Kitcher, (1995) Batali, J. & Kitcher, P. 1995. Evolution of altriusm in optional and compulsory games. J Theor Biol, 175, 161–171.
  • Boyd & Richerson, (1992) Boyd, R. & Richerson, P. J. 1992. Punishment allows the evolution of cooperation (or anything else) in sizable groups. Ethology and Sociobiology, 13 (3), 171–195.
  • Challet & Zhang, (1997) Challet, D. & Zhang, Y.-C. 1997. Emergence of Cooperation and Organization in an Evolutionary Game. Physica A-Statistical Mechanics and Its Applications, 246, 407–418.
  • Cressman, (2003) Cressman, R. 2003. Evolutionary Dynamics and Extensive Form Games. MIT Press, Cambridge.
  • De Silva et al., (2009) De Silva, H., Hauert, C., Traulsen, A. & Sigmund, K. 2009. Freedom, enforcement, and the social dilemma of strong altruism. J Evol Econ, 20 (2), 203–217.
  • Foster & Young, (1990) Foster, D. & Young, P. 1990. Stochastic evolutionary game dynamics. Theor Popul Biol, 38 (2), 219–232.
  • Friedman, (1998) Friedman, D. 1998. On economic applications of evolutionary game theory. J Evol Econ, 8 (1), 15–43.
  • (10) Fu, F., Chen, X., Liu, L. & Wang, L. 2007a. Social dilemmas in an online social network: The structure and evolution of cooperation. Phys Lett A, 371 (1-2), 58–64.
  • (11) Fu, F., Chen, X., Liu, L. & Wang, L. 2007b. Promotion of cooperation induced by the interplay between structure and game dynamics. Physica A-Statistical Mechanics and Its Applications, 383 (2), 651–659.
  • Garcia & Traulsen, (2012) Garcia, J. & Traulsen, A. 2012. The structure of mutations and the evolution of cooperation. Plos One, 7 (4), e35287.
  • Gokhale & Traulsen, (2011) Gokhale, C. S. & Traulsen, A. 2011. Strategy abundance in evolutionary many-player games with multiple strategies. J Theor Biol, 283 (1), 180–191.
  • Hauert, (2002) Hauert, C. 2002. Volunteering as Red Queen Mechanism for Cooperation in Public Goods Games. Science, 296 (5570), 1129–1132.
  • Hauert et al., (2002) Hauert, C., De Monte, S., Hofbauer, J. & Sigmund, K. 2002. Replicator dynamics for optional public good games. J Theor Biol, 218 (2), 187–194.
  • Hauert et al., (2014) Hauert, C., Doebeli, M. & barre, F. D. e. 2014. Social evolution in structured populations. Nat Commun, 5, 3409.
  • Hauert et al., (2006) Hauert, C., Michor, F., Nowak, M. A. & Doebeli, M. 2006. Synergy and discounting of cooperation in social dilemmas. J Theor Biol, 239 (2), 195–202.
  • Hauert et al., (2007) Hauert, C., Traulsen, A., Brandt, H., Nowak, M. A. & Sigmund, K. 2007. Via Freedom to Coercion: The Emergence of Costly Punishment. Science, 316 (5833), 1905–1907.
  • Hilbe & Sigmund, (2010) Hilbe, C. & Sigmund, K. 2010. Incentives and opportunism: from the carrot to the stick. P R Soc B, 277 (1693), 2427–2433.
  • Hofbauer & Sigmund, (1998) Hofbauer, J. & Sigmund, K. 1998. Evolutionary Games and Population Dynamics. Cambridge University Press.
  • Hofbauer & Sigmund, (1988) Hofbauer, J. & Sigmund, K. S. 1988. The theory of evolution and dynamical systems. Cambridge University Press.
  • Imhof & Nowak, (2006) Imhof, L. A. & Nowak, M. A. 2006. Evolutionary game dynamics in a Wright-Fisher process. J. Math. Biol. 52 (5), 667–681.
  • Kitcher, (1993) Kitcher, P. 1993. The evolution of human altruism. The Journal of Philosophy, 90 (10), 497–516.
  • Lieberman et al., (2005) Lieberman, E., Hauert, C. & Nowak, M. A. 2005. Evolutionary dynamics on graphs. Nature, 433 (7023), 312–316.
  • Maciejewski, (2014) Maciejewski, W. 2014. Reproductive value in graph-structured populations. J Theor Biol, 340, 285–293.
  • Michor & Nowak, (2002) Michor, F. & Nowak, M. A. 2002. Evolution: The good, the bad and the lonely. Nature, 419 (6908), 677–679.
  • Nakamaru & Iwasa, (2005) Nakamaru, M. & Iwasa, Y. 2005. The evolution of altruism by costly punishment in lattice-structured populations: score-dependent viability versus score-dependent fertility. Evolutionary ecology research, 7, 853–870.
  • Nakamaru et al., (1997) Nakamaru, M., Matsuda, H. & Iwasa, Y. 1997. The Evolution of Cooperation in a Lattice-Structured Population. J Theor Biol, 184 (1), 65–81.
  • Nowak, (2004) Nowak, M. A. 2004. Evolutionary Dynamics of Biological Games. Science, 303 (5659), 793–799.
  • (30) Nowak, M. A. 2006a. Five Rules for the Evolution of Cooperation. Science, 314 (5805), 1560–1563.
  • (31) Nowak, M. A. 2006b. Evolutionary Dynamics: Exploring the Equations of Life. Harvard University Press, Cambridge.
  • Nowak, (2012) Nowak, M. A. 2012. Evolving cooperation. J Theor Biol, 299, 1–8.
  • Nowak et al., (1994) Nowak, M. A., Bonhoeffer, S. & May, R. M. 1994. Spatial games and the maintenance of cooperation. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 91, 4877–4811.
  • Nowak & May, (1992) Nowak, M. A. & May, R. M. 1992. Evolutionary games and spatial chaos. Nature, 359, 826–829.
  • Nowak et al., (2004) Nowak, M. A., Sasaki, A., Taylor, C. & Fudenberg, D. 2004. Emergence of cooperation and evolutionary stability in finite populations. Nature, 428 (6983), 646–650.
  • Nowak et al., (2010) Nowak, M. A., Tarnita, C. E. & Antal, T. 2010. Evolutionary dynamics in structured populations. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 365 (1537), 19–30.
  • Ohtsuki et al., (2006) Ohtsuki, H., Hauert, C., Lieberman, E. & Nowak, M. A. 2006. A simple rule for the evolution of cooperation on graphs and social networks. Nature, 441 (25), 502–505.
  • Ohtsuki & Nowak, (2006) Ohtsuki, H. & Nowak, M. A. 2006. Evolutionary games on cycles. P R Soc B, 273 (1598), 2249–2256.
  • Perc, (2011) Perc, M. 2011. Does strong heterogeneity promote cooperation by group interactions? New J. Phys. 13 (12), 123027.
  • Perc & Szolnoki, (2010) Perc, M. & Szolnoki, A. 2010. Coevolutionary games—A mini review. Biosystems, 99 (2), 109–125.
  • Rand & Nowak, (2011) Rand, D. G. & Nowak, M. A. 2011. The evolution of antisocial punishment in optional public goods games. Nat Commun, 2, 434.
  • Rand & Nowak, (2013) Rand, D. G. & Nowak, M. A. 2013. Human cooperation. Trends in cognitive sciences, 17 (8), 413–425.
  • Santos & Pacheco, (2005) Santos, F. & Pacheco, J. 2005. Scale-Free Networks Provide a Unifying Framework for the Emergence of Cooperation. Phys. Rev. Lett. 95 (9), 098104.
  • Santos et al., (2008) Santos, F. C., Santos, M. D. & Pacheco, J. M. 2008. Social diversity promotes the emergence of cooperation in public goods games. Nature, 454 (7201), 213–216.
  • Sigmund, (2007) Sigmund, K. 2007. Punish or perish? Retaliation and collaboration among humans. Trends in Ecology & Evolution, 22 (11), 593–600.
  • Szabó & Fáth, (2007) Szabó, G. & Fáth, G. 2007. Evolutionary games on graphs. Physics Reports, 446 (4-6), 97–216.
  • (47) Szabó, G. & Hauert, C. 2002a. Evolutionary prisoner’s dilemma games with voluntary participation. Phys. Rev. E, 66 (6), 062903.
  • (48) Szabó, G. & Hauert, C. 2002b. Phase transitions and volunteering in spatial public goods games. Phys. Rev. Lett. 89 (11), 118101.
  • (49) Tarnita, C. E., Antal, T., Ohtsuki, H. & Nowak, M. A. 2009a. Evolutionary dynamics in set structured populations. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 106 (21), 8601–8604.
  • (50) Tarnita, C. E., Ohtsuki, H., Antal, T., Fu, F. & Nowak, M. A. 2009b. Strategy selection in structured populations. J Theor Biol, 259 (3), 570–581.
  • Tarnita et al., (2011) Tarnita, C. E., Wage, N. & Nowak, M. A. 2011. Multiple strategies in structured populations. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 108 (6), 2334–2337.
  • Taylor et al., (2004) Taylor, C., Fudenberg, D., Sasaki, A. & Nowak, M. A. 2004. Evolutionary game dynamics in finite populations. Bull. Math. Biol. 66 (6), 1621–1644.
  • Traulsen et al., (2009) Traulsen, A., Hauert, C., De Silva, H., Nowak, M. A. & Sigmund, K. 2009. Exploration dynamics in evolutionary games. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 106 (3), 709–712.
  • Traulsen et al., (2006) Traulsen, A., Pacheco, J. M. & Imhof, L. A. 2006. Stochasticity and evolutionary stability. Phys. Rev. E, 74, 021905.
  • Traulsen et al., (2008) Traulsen, A., Shoresh, N. & Nowak, M. A. 2008. Analytical Results for Individual and Group Selection of Any Intensity. Bull. Math. Biol. 70 (5), 1410–1424.
  • van Veelen & Nowak, (2012) van Veelen, M. & Nowak, M. A. 2012. Multi-player games on the cycle. J Theor Biol, 292, 116–128.
  • Vincent & Brown, (2005) Vincent, T. L. & Brown, J. S. 2005. Evolutionary Game Theory, Natural Selection, and Darwinian Dynamics. Cambridge University Press.
  • Weibull, (1997) Weibull, J. W. 1997. Evolutionary Game Theory. MIT Press.
  • Wu et al., (2013) Wu, B., Garcia, J., Hauert, C. & Traulsen, A. 2013. Extrapolating weak selection in evolutionary games. PLoS Comp Biol, 9 (12), e1003381.