This paper was converted on www.awesomepapers.org from LaTeX by an anonymous user.
Want to know more? Visit the Converter page.

Pricing Equity Default Swaps under an approximation to the CGMY Lévy Model

S. Asmussen
Dept. of Mathematical Sciences
Aarhus University
Ny Munkegade
DK-8000 Aarhus C, Denmark
   D. Madan
Robert H. Smith School of Business
Van Munching Hall
University of Maryland
College Park, MD 20742
   M. Pistorius
Dept. of Mathematics
King’s College London
Strand
London WC2R 2LS
U.K
Abstract

The Wiener-Hopf factorization is obtained in closed form for a phase type approximation to the CGMY Lévy process. This allows, for the approximation, exact computation of first passage times to barrier levels via Laplace transform inversion. Calibration of the CGMY model to market option prices defines the risk neutral process for which we infer the first passage times of stock prices to 30% of  the price level at contract initiation. These distributions are then used in pricing 50% recovery rate equity default swap (EDS) contracts and the resulting prices are compared with the prices of credit default swaps (CDS). An illustrative analysis is presented for these contracts on Ford and GM.

Acknowledgement 1

This work was partly completed while all three authors were visiting the Isaac Newton Institute as participants in the “Developments in Quantitative Finance” program. We thank Bruno Dupire and other seminar participants at Bloomberg. We also thank conference participants of the Credit Conference at Edinburgh and the MSRI conference in London.

Acknowledgement 2

In addition Martijn Pistorius acknowledges support from the Nuffield Foundation Grant NAL/00761/G.

1 Introduction

The equity default swap contract has recently been introduced in the financial markets. The contract pays a recovery proportion of a notional amount at the time of the occurence of a specific equity event, up to a maturity, that is typically 55 years. The equity event is defined as the first time the stock price drops below 30%30\% of the price prevailing at contract initiation. The distribution of this first passage time is then of critical importance in the valuation of the contract. These distributions are known for the geometric Brownian motion model and results have also recently been obtained (Davydov and Linetsky (2001), Campi and Sbuelz (2005)) for the constant elasticity of variance (CEV) model. The prices of European options under these models, however, are not consistent with observed market option prices and such observations call into question the resulting swap prices.

Observed market option prices are more closely matched by a variety of pure jump Lévy process models for the evolution of the logarithm of the stock price. Here we shall focus attention on the four parameter CGMYCGMY Lévy model introduced by Carr, Geman, Madan and Yor (2002). First passage times for such Lévy processes require knowledge of the distribution of the supremum and infimum of the process over a fixed time interval. The product of the Laplace transforms of these distributions is known by the famed Wiener-Hopf factorization. Identification of the law of the infimum and supremum then flounders on the inability to analytically perform the factorization. Again, it is known that if the Lévy process has only one-sided jumps, say downwards, then the law of the supremum is known and one may then use the Wiener-Hopf identity to deduce the law of the infimum. Such strategies have been effectively pursued in Rogers (2000), Novikov, Melchers, Shinjikashvili and Kordzakhia (2003), Khanna and Madan (2004) and Chiu and Yin (2005). Processes with one sided jumps are dominated by those with two sided jumps in their ability to explain option prices.

For Lévy processes with two sided jumps the double Laplace transform in time and the level of the infimum and supremum have been derived by Nguyen and Yor (2002) for some Lévy processes using bivariate integral representations. However, the numerical inversion of these transforms involves four integrals and is computationally quite involved. Here we consider an alternative strategy for obtaining the first passage distribution of two sided jump Lévy processes. To this end, we use phase-type distributions, defined as the time until absorption of a finite state continuous-time Markov process (See Asmussen (1992)). It is a well known fact that this class comes close to being complete for obtaining first passage probabilities of the type we consider.

We employ results from Asmussen, Avram and Pistorius (2004) to obtain closed forms for the Laplace transform of first passage distributions for Lévy processes when the Lévy measure has a phase type distribution. In addition to providing tractable computational schemes, phase-type distributions have the advantage of forming a dense class so that by increasing the size of the state space, one can in principle get arbitrarily close to a target density and thereby get arbitrarily good approximations of the first passage probabilities.

A particularly important subclass of phase-type distributions is formed by the hyperexponential distributions, i.e. finite mixtures of exponentials. The underlying Markov process then chooses some initial state, stays there an exponential time with rate depending on the state and goes directly to the absorbing state. This subclass is appealing for the CGMYCGMY Lévy case as the target density is completely monotonic, i.e. a possibly continuous mixture of exponentials, so that by a discretization procedure it is a limit of (possibly scaled) hyperexponential densities. In practice, the fitting can be done either by maximum likelihood (Asmussen, Nerman and Olsson (1996)) as then one wants to capture the shape of the target density, or by minimizing a distance measure paying specific attention to specific features of interest. In particular, in first passage problems a good fit in the tail is crucial, and hyperexponential approximations to Pareto tails have been obtained in this way (Feldman and Whitt (1998)). This is the path we follow in this paper. We approximate the Lévy density of the CGMYCGMY process by a hyperexponential distribution and we then use the first passage time of the approximating  process to determine the Laplace transform of the first passage time distribution for the approximating Lévy process. One dimensional Laplace transform inversions using the methods of Abate and Whitt (1995) then give us both the survival probability and the first passage density for this approximation. One may wish to evaluate the quality of this approximation to an exact result for the CGMYCGMY process. The latter is however not computationally available at this time. One may obtain alternative approximations by either solving partial integro differential equations or by Monte Carlo simulation. The simulation would require the development of appropriate importance sampling methodologies. We therefore leave these questions for future research. The same considerations apply with respect to constructing a priori bounds on the error with respect to the exact result.

From the first passage density and survival probability one may determine the quote on an equity default swap contract. We estimate the CGMYCGMY parameters from the prices of options on Ford and GM over a three year period and extract daily estimates of quotes on equity default swap contracts using the above hyperexponential approximation. We compare these prices with market quotes on the CDSCDS rates and we observe that these two separate sets of prices for a credit event, indeed, correlate well.

The outline of the rest of the paper is as follows. Section 2 presents the details for the construction of the Laplace transform of the first passage time for an approximation to the CGMYCGMY Lévy process. Section 3 describes how this transform is used in quoting on equity default swap contracts. Section 4 presents the results of daily calibration of the CGMYCGMY model to market option prices. Section 5 compares the resulting equity default swap prices with their credit default swap counterparts. Section 6 concludes.

2 The CGMY First Passage Time

We wish to determine the first passage time of the CGMYCGMY Lévy process to various levels using a phase type distribution to approximate the process. For the Laplace transform of the first passage time of the approximating process, i.e. a process with a phase type Lévy measure, we follow Asmussen, Avram and Pistorius (2004). Given that the Lévy measure is completely monotone we may employ a very special phase type distribution that approximates the Lévy measure as a mixture of exponentials. The phase type distribution we employ therefore has a simple form. Starting from an initial state we have an entrance into a number of states where we stay until absorption. There are no transitions between states. Suppose the Lévy measure has the form

k(x)\displaystyle k(x) =\displaystyle= i=1naieαix𝟏x>0\displaystyle\sum_{i=1}^{n}a_{i}e^{-\alpha_{i}x}\mathbf{1}_{x>0} (1)
+j=1mbjeβj|x|𝟏x<0.\displaystyle+\sum_{j=1}^{m}b_{j}e^{-\beta_{j}|x|}\mathbf{1}_{x<0}.

Our phase type distribution for the positive jumps has n+1n+1 states with the generator matrix

T(+)=(α10α2.0αn)T^{(+)}=\left(\begin{array}[]{cccc}-\alpha_{1}&&&0\\ &-\alpha_{2}&&\\ &&.&0\\ &&&-\alpha_{n}\end{array}\right) (2)

with unnormalized initial state probabilities proportional to aiαi\frac{a_{i}}{\alpha_{i}} for the states i=1,,ni=1,\cdots,n and the vector of absorption rates into the final state is

t=(α1,α2,,αn).t=(\alpha_{1},\alpha_{2},\cdots,\alpha_{n}). (3)

The characteristic exponent for the approximation now takes the special form

κ(s)\displaystyle\kappa(s) =\displaystyle= logE[exp(sX1)]\displaystyle\log E\left[\exp\left(sX_{1}\right)\right]
=\displaystyle= μs+λ+i=1nπi+(αiαis1)+λ_j=1mπj(βjβj+s1)+σ22s2\displaystyle\mu s+\lambda_{+}\sum_{i=1}^{n}\pi_{i}^{+}\left(\frac{\alpha_{i}}{\alpha_{i}-s}-1\right)+\lambda_{\_}\sum_{j=1}^{m}\pi_{j}^{-}\left(\frac{\beta_{j}}{\beta_{j}+s}-1\right)+\frac{\sigma^{2}}{2}s^{2}
λ+\displaystyle\lambda^{+} =\displaystyle= i=1naiαi; λ_=j=1mbjβj\displaystyle\sum_{i=1}^{n}\frac{a_{i}}{\alpha_{i}};\text{ }\lambda_{\_}=\sum_{j=1}^{m}\frac{b_{j}}{\beta_{j}} (4)
πi+\displaystyle\pi_{i}^{+} =\displaystyle= aiλ+αi; πj=bjλ_βj.\displaystyle\frac{a_{i}}{\lambda_{+}\alpha_{i}};\text{ }\pi_{j}^{-}=\frac{b_{j}}{\lambda_{\_}\beta_{j}}.

Where the value of σ2\sigma^{2} will depend on the diffusion approximation we incorporate for the small jumps. This is described in greater detail later. The drift μ\mu is chosen to make the overall drift on the stock price be  the interest rate less the dividend yield.

Let TxT_{x} be the first passage time over a level x>0,x>0, the Laplace transform of TxT_{x} at the transform argument aa

E[eaTx]E\left[e^{-aT_{x}}\right]

is obtained in terms of the roots, with positive real part, of the equation

κ(s)=a.\kappa(s)=a. (5)

We observe that one may write

κ(s)=p(s)q(s)\kappa(s)=\frac{p(s)}{q(s)} (6)

as a ratio of two polynomials and so we seek the roots of the polynomial equation

p(s)=aq(s).p(s)=aq(s). (7)

The polynomial q(s)q(s) is

q(s)=i=1n(αis)j=1m(βj+s)q(s)=\prod_{i=1}^{n}(\alpha_{i}-s)\prod_{j=1}^{m}\left(\beta_{j}+s\right) (8)

and

p(s)=q(s)(σ22s2+μs(λ++λ)λ+i=1nπi+αi1sαi+λ_j=1mπjβj1βj+s).p(s)=q(s)\left(\frac{\sigma^{2}}{2}s^{2}+\mu s-\left(\lambda_{+}+\lambda_{-}\right)-\lambda_{+}\sum_{i=1}^{n}\pi_{i}^{+}\alpha_{i}\frac{1}{s-\alpha_{i}}+\lambda_{\_}\sum_{j=1}^{m}\pi_{j}^{-}\beta_{j}\frac{1}{\beta_{j}+s}\right). (9)

We observe that κ(0)=0\kappa(0)=0 and the poles of κ(s)\kappa(s) are exactly equal to the eigenvalues of T(+)-T^{(+)} and those of T()T^{(-)} (and also the roots of q(s)=0q(s)=0).We note that paqp-aq is of degree n+m+2n+m+2 if σ>0\sigma>0 and of degree n+m+1n+m+1 if σ=0,μ>0.\sigma=0,\mu>0. In the case μ>0,\mu>0, σ=0,\sigma=0, κ(s)=a\kappa(s)=a has n+1n+1 distinct positive roots and mm distinct negative roots. If σ>0\sigma>0 κ(s)=a\kappa(s)=a has n+1n+1 distinct positive roots and m+1m+1 distinct negative roots. Finally for μ=0,σ=0\mu=0,\sigma=0 there are nn positive and mm negative distinct roots.

Let k+k_{+} be the number of positive roots. Suppose the positive roots are ρi,\rho_{i}, i=1,,k+i=1,\cdots,k_{+} then letting

Mt=supst(Xs0)M_{t}=\sup_{s\leq t}\left(X_{s}\vee 0\right) (10)

and writing

P(Me(a)dx)=0+aeatP(Mtdx)P\left(M_{e(a)}\in dx\right)=\int_{0^{+}}^{\infty}ae^{-at}P(M_{t}\in dx) (11)

(e(a)e(a) is an independent exponential random variable with mean a1a^{-1}), we have that (for ss with (s)0\mathcal{R}(s)\leq 0)

ϕa+(s)\displaystyle\phi_{a}^{+}(s) =\displaystyle= 0aeatE[esMt]𝑑t\displaystyle\int_{0}^{\infty}ae^{-at}E\left[e^{sM_{t}}\right]dt (12)
=\displaystyle= P(Me(a)=0)+0+esxP(Me(a)dx)\displaystyle P\left(M_{e(a)}=0\right)+\int_{0^{+}}^{\infty}e^{sx}P\left(M_{e(a)}\in dx\right)
=\displaystyle= ϕa+()+0+esxP(Me(a)dx).\displaystyle\phi_{a}^{+}(-\infty)+\int_{0^{+}}^{\infty}e^{sx}P\left(M_{e(a)}\in dx\right).

This function may be expressed in terms of the positive roots ρi\rho_{i} by

ϕa+(s)\displaystyle\phi_{a}^{+}(s) =\displaystyle= det(sIT)det(T).i=1k+(ρi)i=1k+(sρi)\displaystyle\frac{\det\left(-sI-T\right)}{\det\left(-T\right)}.\frac{\prod_{i=1}^{k_{+}}\left(-\rho_{i}\right)}{\prod_{i=1}^{k_{+}}\left(s-\rho_{i}\right)} (13)
=\displaystyle= i=1n(1sαi1)i=1k+(1sρi1)\displaystyle\frac{\prod_{i=1}^{n}\left(1-s\alpha_{i}^{-1}\right)}{\prod_{i=1}^{k_{+}}\left(1-s\rho_{i}^{-1}\right)}

where ρ1,ρk+ \rho_{1},\cdots\rho_{k_{+}\text{ }}are the positive roots of κ(s)=a\kappa(s)=a and where T=diag(αi)T=diag(-\alpha_{i}) is the restriction of T+T^{+} to the nonabsorbing states. If σ=0\sigma=0 the number of positive roots k+k_{+} is equal to the number of positive phases n,n, k+=nk_{+}=n and we note that

ϕa+()=i=1k+ρiαi\phi_{a}^{+}(-\infty)=\prod_{i=1}^{k_{+}}\frac{\rho_{i}}{\alpha_{i}} (14)

and 0<ϕa+()<1.0<\phi_{a}^{+}(-\infty)<1.

If σ>0\sigma>0 then the number of positive roots is k+=n+1k_{+}=n+1 one more than the number of positive phases n:n: ρ1,ρn+1\rho_{1},\cdots\rho_{n+1} and we have the formula

ϕa+(s)=i=1n(1sαi1)i=1n+1(1sρi1)\phi_{a}^{+}(s)=\frac{\prod_{i=1}^{n}\left(1-s\alpha_{i}^{-1}\right)}{\prod_{i=1}^{n+1}\left(1-s\rho_{i}^{-1}\right)} (15)

furthermore, now ϕa+()=limsϕa+(s)\phi_{a}^{+}(-\infty)=\lim_{s\rightarrow-\infty}\phi_{a}^{+}(-s) is zero.

Hence in the case that there is a Brownian component present (σ>0)(\sigma>0)

ϕa+()=0.\phi_{a}^{+}(-\infty)=0. (16)

By performing a partial fraction decomposition we can perform the Laplace inversion in ss analytically: Note that we can write

ϕa+(s)ϕa+()=i=1k+Ai+ρisρi\phi_{a}^{+}(s)-\phi_{a}^{+}(-\infty)=\sum_{i=1}^{k_{+}}A_{i}^{+}\frac{-\rho_{i}}{s-\rho_{i}} (17)

where

Ai+=j=1n(1ρiαj1)j=1,jik+(1ρiρj1).A_{i}^{+}=\frac{\prod_{j=1}^{n}\left(1-\rho_{i}\alpha_{j}^{-1}\right)}{\prod_{j=1,j\neq i}^{k_{+}}\left(1-\rho_{i}\rho_{j}^{-1}\right)}. (18)

The Laplace transform can be inverted explicitly to find for x>0x>0

P(Me(a)<x)=P(Me(a)=0)+i=1k+Ai+(1eρix).P\left(M_{e(a)}<x\right)=P\left(M_{e(a)}=0\right)+\sum_{i=1}^{k_{+}}A_{i}^{+}(1-e^{-\rho_{i}x}). (19)

It follows from the fact that

P(Me(a)<)=1P(M_{e(a)}<\infty)=1 (20)

that

1i=1k+Ai+=P(Me(a)=0)=ϕa+().1-\sum_{i=1}^{k_{+}}A_{i}^{+}=P\left(M_{e(a)}=0\right)=\phi_{a}^{+}(-\infty). (21)

In particular we get that

P(Me(a)>x)\displaystyle P\left(M_{e(a)}>x\right) =\displaystyle= 1P(Me(a)=0)i=1k+Ai+(1eρix)\displaystyle 1-P\left(M_{e(a)}=0\right)-\sum_{i=1}^{k_{+}}A_{i}^{+}(1-e^{-\rho_{i}x}) (22)
=\displaystyle= 1i=1k+Ai+P(Me(a)=0)+i=1k+Ai+eρix\displaystyle 1-\sum_{i=1}^{k_{+}}A_{i}^{+}-P\left(M_{e(a)}=0\right)+\sum_{i=1}^{k_{+}}A_{i}^{+}e^{-\rho_{i}x}
=\displaystyle= i=1k+Ai+eρix.\displaystyle\sum_{i=1}^{k_{+}}A_{i}^{+}e^{-\rho_{i}x}.

Now since

P(Me(a)>x)\displaystyle P\left(M_{e(a)}>x\right) =\displaystyle= 0aeatP(Mt>x)𝑑t\displaystyle\int_{0}^{\infty}ae^{-at}P\left(M_{t}>x\right)dt (23)
=\displaystyle= a0eatP(Tx<t)𝑑t\displaystyle a\int_{0}^{\infty}e^{-at}P\left(T_{x}<t\right)dt

we find the Laplace transform of P(Tx<t)P\left(T_{x}<t\right)

0eatP(Tx<t)𝑑t=1ai=1k+Ai+eρix\int_{0}^{\infty}e^{-at}P\left(T_{x}<t\right)dt=\frac{1}{a}\sum_{i=1}^{k_{+}}A_{i}^{+}e^{-\rho_{i}x} (24)

where ρi=ρi(a)\rho_{i}=\rho_{i}(a) and Ai+=Ai+(a)A_{i}^{+}=A_{i}^{+}(a) depend on a.a.

We employ the methods of Abate and Whitt (1995) to obtain first passage probabilities and the first passage density. We next consider the details for the diffusion approximation and the phase type approximation of the CGMYCGMY process.

2.1 CGMY details

The CGMYCGMY process was introduced in (Carr, Geman, Madan and Yor (2002), see also Koponen (1995), Boyarchenko and Levendorskii (1999, 2000)) and is a pure jump Lévy process with the Lévy density

k(x)=CeMxx1+Y𝟏x>0+CeG|x||x|1+Y𝟏x<0.k(x)=C\frac{e^{-Mx}}{x^{1+Y}}\mathbf{1}_{x>0}+C\frac{e^{-G|x|}}{|x|^{1+Y}}\mathbf{1}_{x<0}. (25)

For this completely monotone Lévy density of the CGMYCGMY process we recognize that

1x1+Y=0uYeuxΓ(1+Y)𝑑u\frac{1}{x^{1+Y}}=\int_{0}^{\infty}\frac{u^{Y}e^{-ux}}{\Gamma(1+Y)}du (26)

and consider the approximation scheme

1x1+Yi=1N1uiYeuix(ui+1ui)Γ(1+Y).\frac{1}{x^{1+Y}}\approx\sum_{i=1}^{N-1}\frac{u_{i}^{Y}e^{-u_{i}x}(u_{i+1}-u_{i})}{\Gamma(1+Y)}. (27)

For a prespecified sequence of exponential decay coefficients uiu_{i} that correspond to reasonable levels of mean jump sizes under the single exponential model. The specific values for uiu_{i} were obtained using a least squares algorithm that minimizes the sum of squared errors between the left hand side of (27) and the right hand side of (27) evaluated at the xx points starting at x=.25x=.25 and increasing to x=5x=5 in steps of .025..025. As starting values we employed .5,2,5,10,20,40.5,2,5,10,20,40 and 100100. Our application works with the value of YY fixed at .5.5 and hence the approximation of equation (27) developed and subsequently used is independent of all parameter variations. The resulting values for uiu_{i} were .1940,.1940, .5982,.5982, .8434,.8434, 1.1399,1.1399, 1.5308,1.5308, 2.1211,2.1211, and 3.4055.3.4055.

We then approximate the CGMYCGMY Lévy density on the two sides by

k+(x)\displaystyle k_{+}(x) =\displaystyle= i=1N1cie(M+ui)x\displaystyle\sum_{i=1}^{N-1}c_{i}e^{-(M+u_{i})x} (28)
k_(x)\displaystyle k_{\_}(x) =\displaystyle= i=1N1die(G+ui)x.\displaystyle\sum_{i=1}^{N-1}d_{i}e^{-(G+u_{i})x}. (29)
ci\displaystyle c_{i} =\displaystyle= di=CuiY(ui+1ui)Γ(1+Y)\displaystyle d_{i}=\frac{Cu_{i}^{Y}(u_{i+1}-u_{i})}{\Gamma(1+Y)} (30)

We then have in terms of our general discussion above

αi=M+ui; βi=G+ui\alpha_{i}=M+u_{i};\text{ }\beta_{i}=G+u_{i} (31)

Alternative but somewhat related procedures for fitting hyperexponentials to general densities (rather than Lévy measures as here) have been considered in Feldman and Whitt (1998), Andersen and Nielsen (1998) and Asmussen, Jobmann and Schwefel (2002).

2.2 First Passage to a low level

For the first passage to a low level we may work with the first passage of X(t)-X(t) to a high level. In this case we reverse the roles of α,β\alpha,\beta and write

αi\displaystyle\alpha_{i} =\displaystyle= G+ui\displaystyle G+u_{i} (32)
βi\displaystyle\beta_{i} =\displaystyle= M+ui.\displaystyle M+u_{i}.

2.3 The small jump diffusion approximation

Above we discussed a procedure to approximate a CGMYCGMY process XX by a Lévy process X1X_{1} with density (1) and to improve the approximation we would like now to approximate the difference by a Brownian motion.

A way to refine the above approximation of XX by X1X_{1} is to approximate the process of small jumps by a Brownian motion. This process of small jumps denoted Z1εZ_{1}^{\varepsilon} is obtained using the Lévy density of XX restricted to (ε,ε).(-\varepsilon,\varepsilon). The process Z1εZ_{1}^{\varepsilon} is approximated by a Brownian motion with variance

σ2=σ2(ε)=εεx2ν(dx).\sigma^{2}=\sigma^{2}(\varepsilon)=\int_{-\varepsilon}^{\varepsilon}x^{2}\nu(dx). (33)

In Asmussen and Rosinski (2001) it is shown that, if ν\nu has no atoms, Z1εZ_{1}^{\varepsilon} weakly converges to a Brownian motion if and only if

limε01εεεx2ν(dx)=.\lim_{\varepsilon\rightarrow 0}\frac{1}{\varepsilon}\int_{-\varepsilon}^{\varepsilon}x^{2}\nu(dx)=\infty. (34)

For a Variance Gamma process this diffusion approximation fails as

limε01ε0εxeax𝑑x<.\lim_{\varepsilon\rightarrow 0}\frac{1}{\varepsilon}\int_{0}^{\varepsilon}xe^{-ax}dx<\infty. (35)

For a CGMYCGMY process with Y>0Y>0 this diffusion approximation is valid, since

limε01ε0εx1Yeax𝑑x=\lim_{\varepsilon\rightarrow 0}\frac{1}{\varepsilon}\int_{0}^{\varepsilon}x^{1-Y}e^{-ax}dx=\infty (36)

(as ν(dx)/dxconst/|x|1+Y\nu(dx)/dx\geq const/|x|^{1+Y} in a neighbourhood of the origin, see Example 2.3 in Asmussen and Rosinski (2001)).

In our CGMYCGMY process approximation we truncated the CGMYCGMY Lévy density at u1=.5u_{1}=.5 on the one hand but, on the other hand, the approximating densities k+(x),k(x)k_{+}(x),k_{-}(x) are taken to start at x=0.x=0. Therefore we apply the diffusion approximation to

k~(x)=(eMx/x1+Yk+(x))𝟏0<x<u1+(eG|x|/|x|1+Yk_(x))𝟏u1<x<0.\widetilde{k}(x)=\left(e^{-Mx}/x^{1+Y}-k_{+}(x)\right)\mathbf{1}_{0<x<u_{1}}+\left(e^{-G|x|}/|x|^{1+Y}-k_{\_}(x)\right)\mathbf{1}_{-u_{1}<x<0}. (37)

3 Equity Default Swap Pricing

We essentially follow the logic for the pricing of credit default swaps, replacing the required survival probabilities and default time densities with the first passage complementary distributions F¯n(C,G,M,Y)\overline{F}_{n}(C,G,M,Y) and the first passage time density fn(C,G,M,Y)f_{n}(C,G,M,Y) as computed by Laplace transform inversion using the approximation methods described above in section 2 for n\ n days or time 360t=n.360t=n.

Like the credit default swap, the equity default swap contract is viewed in two parts, one describing the receipt side of the cash flows and the other the payment side. There is a notional amount MM associated with the receipt side and the actual level of cash flows received is MM times one minus the recovery rate RR on the occurence of the equity event. Our calculations employ a recovery rate of 50%.50\%. These funds are received on the time τ\tau of first passage of the equity to a level below the specified barrier. We employ two barriers in our calculations, these are 50%50\% and 30%30\% of the price at initiation.

Against this stream of receipts the equity default swap holder makes periodic coupon payments, typically until the equity event or the maturity whichever is comes first. At the first passage event date we subtract from the receipts the accrued coupons from the last coupon date before τ\tau to this date. We denote time measured in days by nn and in years by t.t. For each day nn we define the function ζ(n)\zeta(n) that gives the number of days between the end of day nn and the last day on which a coupon was paid. We also denote by NN the maturity of the contract in days while TT is the maturity in years. By convention we take (N,n)=360(T,t)(N,n)=360(T,t).

Let Δ(n)\Delta(n) be the first passage event indicator function that takes the value 11 if the first passage of equity has occurred on or before day nn and is zero otherwise. Further, let kTk_{T} denote the annual coupon rate or the equity default swap rate quoted on the contract for maturity T.T.The cash flow receipts on day n,n, RnR_{n} are then written as

Rn=(Δ(n)Δ(n1))(M(1R)MkT(nζ(n))360).R_{n}=\left(\Delta(n)-\Delta(n-1)\right)\left(M(1-R)-\frac{Mk_{T}(n-\zeta(n))}{360}\right). (38)

Let NPNP denote the number of coupon payment dates and let npjnp_{j} be the day number of the the jthj^{th} payment date. The jthj^{th} payment PjP_{j} occurring on day npjnp_{j} is then given by

Pj=MkT(npjnpj1)360(1Δ(npj)),P_{j}=\frac{Mk_{T}\left(np_{j}-np_{j-1}\right)}{360}\left(1-\Delta(np_{j})\right), (39)

where the multiplication by the complementary first passage event indicator function recognizes that no coupon payments are made after the first passage event.

For the valuation of claims we employ a discount function BnB_{n} that gives the present value of a dollar promised on day n.n. There are a variety of approaches to constructing such discount functions.

The random present value of cash flows to the equity default swap contract, V(T)V(T) is then given by

V(T)=n=1NRnBnj=1NPPjBnpj.V(T)=\sum_{n=1}^{N}R_{n}B_{n}-\sum_{j=1}^{NP}P_{j}B_{np_{j}}. (40)

We are supposing here that conditional on the outcome of the first passage event the expected values of future dollars are the same. This is equivalent to supposing that the first passage events of single names in the economy do not contain any information about macro movements in interest rates or that interest rate evolutions are independent of the first passage process. We leave for future research the modeling of joint evolutions of interest rates and first passage times.

The equity default swap quotes in markets are set at levels consistent with a zero price at the initiation of the swap contract. Hence we have that under the risk neutral measure

EQ[V(T)]=0.E^{Q}\left[V(T)\right]=0. (41)

From our risk neutral distribution for the first passage time we employ

EQ[(1Δ(n))]=DefF¯n(C,G,M,Y).E^{Q}\left[(1-\Delta(n))\right]\underset{Def}{=}\overline{F}_{n}(C,G,M,Y). (42)

The probability of first passage on a particular day nn may be approximated by the density of default times the length of the day in years.

EQ[(Δ(n)Δ(n1))]=Defπn(C,G,M,Y)\displaystyle E^{Q}\left[(\Delta(n)-\Delta(n-1))\right]\underset{Def}{=}\pi_{n}(C,G,M,Y) (43)
\displaystyle\approx fn(C,G,M,Y)1365.\displaystyle f_{n}(C,G,M,Y)\frac{1}{365}.

We may then compute the value of the equity default swap quote as

EQ[V(T)]\displaystyle E^{Q}\left[V(T)\right] =\displaystyle= n=1N[M(1R)MkT(nζ(n))360]Bnπn(C,G,M,Y)\displaystyle\sum_{n=1}^{N}\left[M(1-R)-\frac{Mk_{T}(n-\zeta(n))}{360}\right]B_{n}\pi_{n}(C,G,M,Y)- (44)
j=1NPMkT(npjnpj1)360BnpjF¯npj(C,G,M,Y).\displaystyle\sum_{j=1}^{NP}\frac{Mk_{T}(np_{j}-np_{j-1})}{360}B_{np_{j}}\overline{F}_{np_{j}}(C,G,M,Y).

Setting this value to zero and solving for the kTk_{T} we obtain the CGMYCGMY equity default swap pricing model

kT(C,G,M,Y)=(1R)n=1NBnπn(C,G,M,Y)j=1NP(npjnpj1)360BnpjF¯npj(C,G,M,Y)+n=1Nnζ(n)360Bnπn(C,G,M,Y).k_{T}(C,G,M,Y)=\frac{(1-R)\sum_{n=1}^{N}B_{n}\pi_{n}(C,G,M,Y)}{\sum_{j=1}^{NP}\frac{(np_{j}-np_{j-1})}{360}B_{np_{j}}\overline{F}_{np_{j}}(C,G,M,Y)+\sum_{n=1}^{N}\frac{n-\zeta(n)}{360}B_{n}\pi_{n}(C,G,M,Y)}. (45)

Equation (45) provides us with a four parameter equity default swap pricing model and the parameters may be estimated from market prices of options on the underlying name. In this way we obtain option implied quotes for the equity default swap rates.

By way of a stylized example we set the interest rate yield curve at a flat 5%5\% level and used the values C=.5,C=.5, G=2,G=2, M=10,M=10, and Y=.5Y=.5 with recovery at 50%50\% and obtained the EDSEDS prices for maturities of 1,1, 3,3, and 55 years at 161.97,161.97, 336.65336.65 and 439.54.439.54.

4 CGMY Calibration to Option Data

We obtained daily data on 55 year CDSCDS rates on Ford and GM over the period 25 February 2002 to 25 February 2005. There were 696696 trading days in this time interval. The credit default swap rates on these names saw a sharp increase over this period before they finally came down again. The mean CDS rates over this period were 308308 for Ford and 249249 for GM. The standard deviations were 132132 and 7878 respectively while the minimum rates were 155155 and 115115 respectively. The corresponding maximal rates were 720720 and 480.480.

We employ the above algorithm to compute option implied equity default swap rates with barriers for the equity event set at the typical value of 30%30\% of initiation price and a five year maturity. For this purpose we calibrate the CGMYCGMY model to European option prices for each day on each name. Equity option prices on Ford and GM traded on the New York Stock Exchange are typically available for American options. We mitigate the American feature by first employing out of the money options. Second we infer implied volatilities from American option prices using the Black Scholes model and then construct the corresponding European prices by the Black Scholes formula. The data is obtained from OptionMetrics and is available at WRDSWRDS the Wharton Research Data Service.

We note that the case Y=0Y=0 is the variance gamma model, that successfully calibrates any of the maturities. We are also aware that we may calibrate equally well with any specific value of the parameter Y.Y. For our approximations to have a diffusion component we require Y>0Y>0 and the structure of the approximation is determined for any fixed value of Y.Y. We therefore froze the value of the YY parameter at Y=.5Y=.5 and calibrated the parameters CGMCGM for this frozen value of Y.Y. The calibrations were done using maturities between 11 and 22 years, by minimizing the root mean square error between market and model European option prices.  We report in TableTable 11 summary statistics of the CGMCGM parameters for both the companies.

TABLE 1
FORD GM
C G M C G M
Median .6506 1.9458 11.0187 .2171 1.0084 5.8031
25% .3661 1.3066 9.9309 .1664 .6690 4.7486
75% 1.0895 4.0969 11.3522 .5582 2.7802 11.5872

5 Equity Default Swap Rates and the CDS Rates

We employed the calibrated CGMCGM model with Y=.5Y=.5 to determine the equity default swap rates for the typical barrier of 30%30\% for the payout on the equity event. We present graphs of the implied EDS and CDS rates for both companies over the 2002-2005 period evaluated every five days. The  data on CDSCDS rates for the five year maturity are readily available from Bloomberg.

Figure 1: Ford CDS in Blue, EDS in Red

Figure 2: GM CDS in Blue EDS in Red

The results of regressing the CDS rates on the EDS rates are as follows. We observe that there is a strong link between between the prices obtained from these separate markets.

FORDFORD GMGM
ConstConst SlopeSlope R2R^{2} ConstConst SlopeSlope R2R^{2}
valuevalue 99.182099.1820 0.29130.2913 0.89500.8950 146.2816146.2816 0.14420.1442 0.62920.6292
tvaluet-value 13.6213.62 33.3733.37 18.1018.10 14.8914.89

6 Conclusion

Approximation of the CGMYCGMY Lévy measure by hyperexponentials leads to an exact Wiener-Hopf factorization of the approximating process and hence to exact expressions for the first passage time of the approximating process to a level. We then employ these results to obtain closed form formulas for the prices of equity default swap contracts that payout on the equity event of a loss of 70%70\% of the initial stock value with the receipts being a regular coupon paid till the equity event or maturity, whichever is less.

The methods are illustrated on CGMYCGMY processes calibrated to the vanilla options market for FORDFORD and GMGM over the period 2525 February 20022002 to 2525 February 2005.2005. For the same period we also observe the daily values of the credit default swap contracts and these are compared favorably with the option imputed equity default swap prices computed by the CGMYCGMY approximation method proposed here.


References

  • [1] Abate, J. and W. Whitt (1995), “Numerical Inversion of Laplace Transforms of Probability Distributions,  ORSA, Journal of Computing, 7, 36-43.
  • [2] Andersen, A. and B.F.Nielsen (1998), “A Markovian approach for modeling packet traffic with dependence,” IEEE J. Sel. Areas Comm., 16, 719-732.
  • [3] Asmussen, S. (1992), “Phase-type representations in random walk and queueing problems,” Annals of Probability, 20, 772-789.
  • [4] Asmussen, S., F. Avram and M. Pistorius (2004), “Russian and American put options under exponential phase-type Lévy models,” Stochastic Processes and their Applications, 109, 79-111.
  • [5] Asmussen, S., M. Jobmann and H.P. Schwefel (2002), “Exact buffer overflow calculations for queues via martingales,” Queueing Systems, 42, 63-90.
  • [6] Asmussen, S., O. Nerman and M. Olsson (1996), “Fitting phase-type distributions via the EM algorithm,” Scandinavian Journal of Statistics, 23, 419-441.
  • [7] Asmussen, S. and J. Rosinski (2001), “Approximations of small jumps of Lévy prosesses with a view towards simulation,” Journal of Applied Probability, 38, 2, 482-493.
  • [8] Boyarchenko, S.I. and Levendorskii (2000), “Option pricing for Truncated Lévy processes,” International Journal for Theory and Applications in Finance, 3, 549-552.
  • [9] Campi, L. and A. Sbuelz (2005), “Closed-form pricing of Benchmark Equity Default Swaps under the CEV assumption,” Working Paper, Finance Department, Tilburg University.
  • [10] Carr, P., H. Geman, D. Madan, and M. Yor (2002), “The Fine Structure of Asset Returns: An Empirical Investigation,” Journal of Business, 75, 2, 305-332.
  • [11] Chiu, S.N. and C. Yin (2005), “Passage times for a spectrally negative Levy process with applications to risk theory,” Bernoulli, 11, 511-522.
  • [12] Davydov, D. and V. Linetsky (2001), “Pricing and hedging path dependent options under the CEV process,” Management Science, 47, 949-965.
  • [13] Feldman, A. and W. Whitt (1998), “Fitting Mixtures of Exponentials to long-tailed distributions to analyze performance models,” Performance Evaluation, 31, 245-279.
  • [14] Khanna, A. and D. Madan (2004), “Understanding Option Prices,” Quantitative Finance, 4, 55-63.
  • [15] Koponen, I. (1995), “Analytic Approach to the problem of convergence of truncated Lévy flights towards the Gaussian stochastic process,” Physical Review E52, 1197-1199.
  • [16] Nguyen-Ngoc, L. and M. Yor (2002), “Exotic Options and Lévy Processes,” to appear in Eds. Yacine Aït Sahalia and Lars Peter Hansen, Handbook of Financial Econometrics, North Holland.
  • [17] Novikov, A., R.E. Melchers, E. Shinjikashvili and N. Kordzakhia (2003), “First Passage Times of Filtered Poisson Process with Exponential Shape Function,” Working Paper, University of Technology, Sydney.
  • [18] Rogers, L.C.G. (2000), “Evaluating first-passage probabilities for spectrally one-sided Lévy processes,” Journal of Applied Probability, 37, 1173-1180.